What if we paid doctors to keep people healthy Matthias Mllenbeck

It’s 4am in the morning.

I’m waking up in a Boston hotel room

and can only think of one thing:

tooth pain.

One of my ceramic inlays
fell off the evening before.

Five hours later,
I’m sitting in a dentist’s chair.

But instead of having a repair of my inlay
so that I can get rid of my pain,

the dentist pitches me on the advantages
of a titanium implant surgery.

Ever heard of that?

(Laughter)

It essentially means to replace
a damaged tooth

by an artificial one,

that is screwed into your jaw.

Estimated costs for the implant surgery
may add up to 10,000 US dollars.

Replacing the ceramic inlay I had before

would come in at 100 US dollars.

Was it my health or the money
that could be earned with me

that was the biggest concern
for my dentist?

As it turned out, my experience
wasn’t an isolated case.

A study by a US national newspaper
estimated that in the United States,

up to 30 percent of all
surgical procedures –

including stent
and pacemaker implantations,

hip replacements and uterus removals –

were conducted

although other nonsurgical treatment
options had not been fully exploited

by the physician in charge.

Isn’t that figure shocking?

Numbers may be slightly different
in other countries,

but what it means is that
if you go to a doctor in the US,

you have a not-insignificant chance
to be subjected to a surgical intervention

without there being
an immediate need for it.

Why is this?

Why are some practitioners incentivized
to run such unnecessary procedures?

Well, perhaps it is because
health care systems themselves

incentivize in a nonideal way

towards applying or not applying
certain procedures or treatments.

As most health care systems
reimburse practitioners

in a fee-for-service-based fashion

on the number and kind
of treatments performed,

it may be this economic incentive
that tempts some practitioners

to rather perform high-profit
surgical treatments

instead of exploring
other treatment options.

Although certain countries
started to implement

performance-based reimbursement,

anchored on a quality and efficacy matrix,

overall, there’s very little in today’s
health care systems' architecture

to incentivize practitioners broadly

to actively prevent the appearance
of a disease in the first place

and to limit the procedures
applied to a patient

to the most effective options.

So how do we fix this?

What it may take is a fundamental redesign

of our health care
system’s architecture –

a complete rethinking
of the incentive structure.

What we may need is a health care system

that reimburses practitioners
for keeping their customers healthy

instead of almost only paying for services
once people are already sick.

What we may need is a transformation

from today’s system
that largely cares for the sick,

to a system that cares for the healthy.

To change our current “sick care” approach

into a true “health care” approach.

It is a paradigm shift from treating
people once they have become sick

to preserving the health of the healthy
before they get sick.

This shift may move the focus
of all those involved –

from doctors, to hospitals,
to pharmaceutical and medical companies –

on the product that this industry
ultimately sells:

health.

Imagine the following.

What if we redesign our health care system

into one that does not
reimburse practitioners

for the actual procedures
performed on a patient

but rather reimburses doctors, hospitals,

pharmaceutical and medical companies

for every day a single
individual is kept healthy

and doesn’t develop a disease?

In practical terms, we could, for example,

use public money to pay a health fee
to an insurance company

for every day a single individual
is kept healthy

and doesn’t develop a disease

or doesn’t require any other form
of acute medical intervention.

If the individual becomes sick,

the insurance company will not receive
any further monetary compensation

for the medical interventions required
to treat the disease of that individual,

but they would be obliged to pay
for every evidence-based treatment option

to return the customer back to health.

Once the customer’s healthy again,

the health fee for that individual
will be paid again.

In effect, all players in the system

are now responsible for keeping
their customers healthy,

and they’re incentivized to avoid
any unnecessary medical interventions

by simply reducing the number of people
that eventually become sick.

The more healthy people there are,

the less the cost
to treat the sick will be,

and the higher the economic benefit
for all parties being involved

in keeping these individuals healthy is.

This change of the incentive
structure shifts, now,

the attention of the complete
health care system

away from providing isolated
and singular treatment options,

towards a holistic view of what is useful

for an individual
to stay healthy and live long.

Now, to effectively preserve health,

people will need to be willing
to share their health data

on a constant basis,

so that the health care system
understands early enough

if any assistance with regard
to their health is needed.

Physical examination,

monitoring of lifetime health data

as well as genetic sequencing,
cardiometabolic profiling

and imaging-based technologies

will allow customers to make,

together with health coaches
and general practitioners,

optimal and science-guided decisions –

for their diet, their medication
and their physical activity –

to diminish their unique probability

to fall sick of an identified,
individual high-risk disease.

Artificial intelligence-based
data analysis

and the miniaturization
of sensor technologies

are already starting to make monitoring
of the individual health status possible.

Measuring cardiometabolic parameters
by devices like this

or the detection of circulating
tumor DNA in your bloodstream

early on after cancer disease onset

are only two examples
for such monitoring technologies.

Take cancer.

One of the biggest problems
in certain oncological diseases

is that a large number of patients
is diagnosed too late

to allow them to be cured,

although the drugs and treatments
that could potentially have cured them

are already existing today,

if the disease had only
been detected earlier.

New technologies allow now,
based on a few milliliters of blood,

to detect the presence
of circulating tumor DNA

and thus, the presence of cancer,

early on in a really convenient manner.

The impact that this early-stage
detection can have

may be dramatic.

The five-year survival rate
for non-small cell lung cancer

when diagnosed at stage one,
which is early, is 49 percent.

The same, when diagnosed
at stage four, which is late,

is below one percent.

Being potentially able
to prevent a large number of deaths

by something as simple as a blood test
for circulating tumor DNA

could make certain cancer types
a manageable disease,

as disease onset can be detected earlier

and positive treatment outcomes
can likely be increased.

In 2012,

50 percent of all Americans
had a single chronic disease,

resulting in 86 percent
of the $3 trillion US health care budget

being spent for treating
such chronic diseases.

Eighty-six percent.

If new technologies allow now
to reduce this 86 percent,

why have health care systems
not reacted and changed already?

Well, a redesign of what today
is a sick care system

into a true health care system
that focuses on prevention

and behavioral changes

requires every actor
in the system to change.

It requires the political willingness
to shift budgets and policies

towards prevention and health education

to design a new set of financial
and non-financial incentives.

It requires creating
a regulatory framework

for the gathering, using and sharing
of personal health data

that’s at the same time
stringent and sensible.

It needs doctors, hospitals, insurers,
pharmaceutical and medical companies

to reframe their approach
and, most important,

it can’t happen without
the willingness and motivation

of individuals to change their lifestyle
in a sustained way,

to prioritize staying healthy,

in addition to opening up for sharing
the health data on a constant basis.

This change may not come overnight.

But by refocusing the incentives
within the health care industry today

to actively keep people healthy,

we may not only be able to prevent
more diseases in the first place

but we may also be able to detect
the onset of certain preventable diseases

earlier than we do today,

which will lead to longer
and healthier lives for more people.

Most of the technologies
that we need to initiate that change

are already existing today.

But this is not a technology question.

It is primarily a question of vision

and will.

Thanks a lot.

(Applause)