Why good ideas get trapped in the valley of death and how to rescue them

They’ve passed every test, cleared every
hurdle, jumped through every hoop.

Now, all that remains is to unleash
them on the world.

But wait— what’s this?

Ah, yes, there’s one more challenge.
They must now across the valley of death.

All new products must pass through
here before they reach the market.

Many never make it out,
and sometimes that’s OK—

if they don’t work, don’t fill a need,
or for any number of other reasons.

But inventions that could help address
massive global issues also face this risk.

That’s because a technology’s potential
isn’t the only factor

that determines whether it will succeed.

The valley of death is especially risky
for innovations

involving complex physical objects
as opposed to software,

and for those in highly regulated
industries,

like medicine, building materials,
and transportation.

Regulations and other obstacles
aren’t inherently bad—

they’re often designed
to keep people safe—

but they do tend to scare off investors,

and that’s what traps good ideas
in the valley of death:

their funding dries up before
they can become profitable.

One of the fields where this problem
is most pressing today

is zero-carbon technologies.

They’re essential to our future

because they will help us eliminate
greenhouse gas emissions

and stabilize our climate.

But they also have features that make
them particularly vulnerable

in the valley of death.

Let’s look at why that is,
and how we can change it.

All new technologies must go
through a development phase

before they can become profitable.

For zero-carbon technologies,

the costs of this phase are high,
the timelines are long,

and, in spite of the good they can do,

demand is often low because they can
require big changes

in both infrastructure
and consumer behavior.

For example, electric heat pumps
don’t burn fossil fuels and,

when you factor in savings on energy use,

are cost-competitive with gas furnaces,

but homeowners only change their heating
and cooling systems every few decades.

Direct air capture technologies,
meanwhile,

remove CO2 directly from the atmosphere.

We need these technologies
to reach our emissions goals,

and several of them have already
been proven to work,

but they’re at risk of getting trapped
in the valley of death

because they’re expensive.

This creates a vicious cycle because
the best way to lower costs

is by, well, practicing:
making more of a product and refining it.

But high initial costs
scare off investors,

and without their money,

companies can’t continue to develop
their technologies—

and can’t ultimately decrease costs.

Fortunately, there’s a way
to break this cycle:

governments can help close the gap,

when private investors won’t fund
technologies

with such a high potential
for social benefit.

This isn’t just theoretical:

in the 1990s,
functioning solar panels existed,

but weren’t widely adopted
because of their cost.

To change this, Germany offered government
loans to companies creating solar panels,

and legally obligated utility companies

to buy electricity produced
using renewable energy.

The U.S. and China followed suit
by financing major solar panel projects.

The cost of solar has dropped
almost 90% since 2009,

making it much easier to adopt.

A similar thing happened for wind energy:

during the oil crisis of the 1970s,
Denmark invested in wind power

and started taxing winds’
fossil fuel-based competitors.

Other countries took similar steps,

and as more wind power was
generated worldwide,

the costs of this technology
dropped dramatically.

These success stories tell us
that government initiatives work—

initiatives like boosting spending
on research and development,

offering tax and loan incentives
to startups

that want to develop
zero-carbon technologies

and consumers who want to buy them,
and putting a price on carbon emissions.

We need governments
to do what they did for solar and wind

for many more innovations.

At the end of the day,
ideas and inventions alone

can’t solve our most daunting problems—

policies and markets have to be shaped

so the most promising technologies
can succeed.

他们通过了每一个测试,清除了每一个
障碍,跳过了每一圈。

现在,剩下的就是将
它们释放到世界上。

但是等等——这是什么?

啊,是的,还有一个挑战。
他们现在必须越过死亡之谷。

所有新产品都必须经过
这里才能进入市场。

许多人从来没有成功
,有时这没关系——

如果他们不工作,不满足需求,
或者出于任何其他原因。

但可以帮助解决
大规模全球问题的发明也面临着这种风险。

这是因为一项技术的潜力

并不是决定它能否成功的唯一因素。

对于

涉及复杂物理
对象而非软件的创新,

以及

医药、建筑材料
和运输等高度监管行业的创新而言,死亡之谷的风险尤其大。

法规和其他障碍
本质上并不坏——

它们通常
旨在保护人们的安全——

但它们确实往往会吓跑投资者

,这就是将好的想法困
在死亡之谷的原因:

他们的资金在盈利之前就枯竭了
. 当今

这个问题最紧迫的领域
之一

是零碳技术。

它们对我们的未来至关重要,

因为它们将帮助我们消除
温室气体排放

并稳定我们的气候。

但它们也具有使
它们

在死亡谷中特别脆弱的特征。

让我们看看为什么会这样,
以及我们如何改变它。

所有新技术都必须
经过开发阶段

才能盈利。

对于零碳技术,

这一阶段的成本很高
,时间线很长,

而且,尽管它们可以做得很好,但

需求通常很低,因为它们可能
需要

对基础设施
和消费者行为进行重大改变。

例如,电热泵
不燃烧化石燃料,

如果考虑到能源使用的节省,

它与燃气炉相比具有成本竞争力,

但房主
每隔几十年才更换一次加热和冷却系统。 与此同时

,直接空气捕获技术

直接从大气中去除二氧化碳。

我们需要这些技术
来实现我们的排放目标,

其中一些技术已经
被证明是有效的,

但它们有被困
在死亡之谷的风险,

因为它们价格昂贵。

这造成了一个恶性循环,因为
降低成本的最佳方法

是通过实践:
制造更多产品并对其进行改进。

但是高昂的初始成本
吓跑了投资者

,没有他们的钱,

公司就无法继续开发
他们的技术

——也无法最终降低成本。

幸运的是,有一种方法
可以打破这个循环:

当私人投资者不会资助

具有如此高
社会效益潜力的技术时,政府可以帮助缩小差距。

这不仅仅是理论上的:

在 1990 年代,
存在功能性太阳能电池板,

但由于成本原因并未被广泛采用

为了改变这一点,德国向
制造太阳能电池板的公司提供政府贷款,

并依法要求公用事业

公司购买
使用可再生能源生产的电力。

美国和中国紧随
其后,为大型太阳能电池板项目提供资金。 自 2009 年以来

,太阳能的成本下降了
近 90%,

使其更易于采用。

风能也发生了类似的事情:

在 1970 年代的石油危机期间,
丹麦投资了风能,

并开始对风能以
化石燃料为基础的竞争对手征税。

其他国家也采取了类似的步骤

,随着全球风力发电量

的增加,这项技术的成本
急剧下降。

这些成功案例告诉我们
,政府的举措奏效了——

诸如增加
研发支出、

想要开发
零碳技术的初创公司

和想要购买这些技术的消费者提供税收
和贷款激励以及为碳排放定价等举措。

我们需要政府
为更多创新做他们为太阳能和风能所做的事情

归根结底,
仅靠想法和发明

并不能解决我们最棘手的问题

——必须塑造政策和市场,

以便最有前途的技术
能够成功。