Economic growth has stalled. Lets fix it Dambisa Moyo

Our ability to create
and sustain economic growth

is the defining challenge of our time.

Of course there are other challenges –

health care, disease burdens
and pandemics,

environmental challenges

and, of course, radicalized terrorism.

However,

to the extent that we can actually
solve the economic growth challenge,

it will take us a long way

to solving the challenges
that I’ve just elucidated.

More importantly,

unless and until we solve economic growth

and create sustainable,
long-term economic growth,

we’ll be unable to address

the seemingly intractable challenges
that continue to pervade the globe today,

whether it’s health care,
education or economic development.

The fundamental question is this:

How are we going to create economic growth

in advanced and developed economies
like the United States and across Europe

at a time when they continue to struggle

to create economic growth
after the financial crisis?

They continue to underperform

and to see an erosion in the three
key drivers of economic growth:

capital, labor and productivity.

In particular,

these developed economies
continue to see debts and deficits,

the decline and erosion
of both the quality and quantity of labor

and they also see productivity stalling.

In a similar vein,

how are we going to create
economic growth in the emerging markets,

where 90 percent
of the world’s population lives

and where, on average,

70 percent of the population
is under the age of 25?

In these countries,

it is essential that they grow
at a minimum of seven percent a year

in order to put a dent in poverty

and to double per capita incomes
in one generation.

And yet today,

the largest emerging economies –

countries with at least
50 million people –

continue to struggle to reach
that seven percent magic mark.

Worse than that,

countries like India, Russia,
South Africa, Brazil and even China

are falling below
that seven percent number

and, in many cases, actually regressing.

Economic growth matters.

With economic growth,

countries and societies
enter into a virtuous cycle

of upward mobility, opportunity
and improved living standards.

Without growth,
countries contract and atrophy,

not just in the annals
of economic statistics

but also in the meaning of life
and how lives are lived.

Economic growth matters
powerfully for the individual.

If growth wanes,

the risk to human progress

and the risk of political
and social instability rises,

and societies become dimmer,
coarser and smaller.

The context matters.

And countries in emerging markets

do not need to grow at the same
rates as developed countries.

Now, I know some of you in this room
find this to be a risky proposition.

There are some people here

who will turn around
and be quite disillusioned

by what’s happened around the world

and basically ascribe that
to economic growth.

You worry about the
overpopulation of the planet.

And looking at the UN’s
recent statistics and projections

that the world will have
11 billion people on the planet

before it plateaus in 2100,

you’re concerned about what that does
to natural resources –

arable land, potable water,
energy and minerals.

You are also concerned about
the degradation of the environment.

And you worry about how man,

embodied in the corporate globalist,

has become greedy and corrupt.

But I’m here to tell you today
that economic growth

has been the backbone
of changes in living standards

of millions of people around the world.

And more importantly,

it’s not just economic growth
that has been driven by capitalism.

The definition of capitalism,
very simply put,

is that the factors of production,

such as trade and industry,
capital and labor,

are left in the hands
of the private sector and not the state.

It’s really essential here
that we understand

that fundamentally the critique
is not for economic growth per se

but what has happened to capitalism.

And to the extent that we need to create
economic growth over the long term,

we’re going to have to pursue it
with a better form of economic stance.

Economic growth needs capitalism,

but it needs it to work properly.

And as I mentioned a moment ago,

the core of the capitalist system
has been defined by private actors.

And even this, however,
is a very simplistic dichotomy.

Capitalism: good; non-capitalism: bad.

When in practical experience,

capitalism is much more of a spectrum.

And we have countries such as China,

which have practiced
more state capitalism,

and we have countries
like the Unites States

which are more market capitalist.

Our efforts to critique
the capitalist system, however,

have tended to focus
on countries like China

that are in fact
not blatantly market capitalism.

However, there is
a real reason and real concern

for us to now focus our attentions
on purer forms of capitalism,

particularly those embodied
by the United States.

This is really important

because this type of capitalism

has increasingly
been afforded the critique

that it is now fostering corruption

and, worse still,

it’s increasing income inequality –

the idea that the few are benefiting
at the expense of the many.

The two really critical questions
that we need to address

is how can we fix capitalism

so that it can help create economic growth

but at the same time
can help to address social ills.

In order to think about that framing,
we have to ask ourselves,

how does capitalism work today?

Very simplistically,

capitalism is set on the basis
of an individual utility maximizer –

a selfish individual
who goes after what he or she wants.

And only after they’ve
maximized their utility

do they then decide it’s important

to provide support
to other social contracts.

Of course, in this system
governments do tax,

and they use part of their revenues
to fund social programs,

recognizing that government’s role
is not just regulation

but also to be arbiter of social goods.

But nevertheless,

this framework –

this two-stage framework –

is the basis from which we must now start

to think about how we can
improve the capitalist model.

I would argue that there are
two sides to this challenge.

First of all,

we can draw on the right-wing policies

to see what could be beneficial for us

to think about how
we can improve capitalism.

In particular,

right-leaning policies

have tended to focus on things
like conditional transfers,

where we pay and reward people
for doing the things

that we actually think
can help enhance economic growth.

For example,

sending children to school,

parents could earn money for that,

or getting their children
inoculated or immunized,

parents could get paid for doing that.

Now, quite apart from the debate

on whether or not
we should be paying people

to do what we think they should do anyway,

the fact of the matter
is that pay for performance

has actually yielded some positive results

in places like Mexico,

in Brazil

and also in pilot programs in New York.

But there are also benefits

and significant changes underway
on left-leaning policies.

Arguments that government should
expand its role and responsibility

so that it’s not so narrowly defined

and that government should be
much more of an arbiter

of the factors of production

have become commonplace
with the success of China.

But also we’ve started to have debates

about how the role of the private sector

should move away
from just being a profit motive

and really be more engaged
in the delivery of social programs.

Things like the corporate
social responsibility programs,

albeit small in scale,

are moving in that right direction.

Of course, left-leaning policies
have also tended to blur the lines

between government,
NGOs and private sector.

Two very good examples of this
are the 19th-century United States,

when the infrastructure rollout

was really about
public-private partnerships.

More recently, of course,

the advent of the Internet
has also proven to the world

that public and private can work together
for the betterment of society.

My fundamental message to you is this:

We cannot continue to try and solve
the world economic growth challenges

by being dogmatic
and being unnecessarily ideological.

In order to create sustainable,
long-term economic growth

and solve the challenges and social ills
that continue to plague the world today,

we’re going to have to be
more broad-minded

about what might work.

Ultimately,

we have to recognize
that ideology is the enemy of growth.

Thank you.

(Applause)

Bruno Giussani: I want to ask
a couple of questions, Dambisa,

because one could react
to your last sentence

by saying growth is also an ideology,

it’s possibly the dominant
ideology of our times.

What do you say
to those who react that way?

DM: Well, I think that that’s
completely legitimate,

and I think that we’re already
having that discussion.

There’s a lot of work
going on around happiness

and other metrics being used
for measuring people’s success

and improvements in living standards.

And so I think that we should be open

to what could deliver improvements
in people’s living standards

and continue to reduce
poverty around the world.

BG: So you’re basically pleading
for rehabilitating growth,

but the only way for that happen

without compromising
the capacity of the earth,

to take us on a long journey,

is for economic growth

somehow to decouple
from the underlying use of resources.

Do you see that happening?

DM: Well, I think that I’m more optimistic
about human ability and ingenuity.

I think if we start to constrain ourselves

using the finite, scarce
and depleting resources

that we know today,

we could get quite negative

and quite concerned
about the way the world is.

However, we’ve seen the Club of Rome,

we’ve seen previous claims

that the world would be
running out of resources,

and it’s not to argue
that those things are not valid.

But I think, with ingenuity
we could see desalination,

I think we could reinvest in energy,

so that we can actually
get better outcomes.

And so in that sense,

I’m much more optimistic
about what humans can do.

BG: The thing that strikes me

about your proposals
for rehabilitating growth

and taking a different direction

is that you’re kind of suggesting
to fix capitalism with more capitalism –

with putting a price tag
on good behavior as incentive

or developing a bigger role
for business in social issues.

Is that what you’re suggesting?

DM: I’m suggesting
we have to be open-minded.

I think it is absolutely the case

that traditional models of economic growth

are not working the way
we would like them to.

And I think it’s no accident

that today the largest
economy in the world, the United States,

has democracy,

liberal democracy,
as it’s core political stance

and it has free market capitalism –

to the extent that it is free –

free market capitalism
as its economic stance.

The second largest economy is China.

It has deprioritized democracy

and it has state capitalism,
which is a completely different model.

These two countries,
completely different political models

and completely different economic models,

and yet they have the same
income inequality number

measured as a Gini coefficient.

I think those are the debates
we should have,

because it’s not clear at all

what model we should be adopting,

and I think there needs to be
much more discourse

and much more humility
about what we know and what we don’t know.

BG: One last question.
The COP21 is going on in Paris.

If you could send a tweet

to all the heads of state
and heads of delegations there,

what would you say?

DM: Again, I would be very much
about being open-minded.

As you’re aware,

the issues around
the environmental concerns

have been on the agenda many times now –

in Copenhagen,
‘72 in Stockholm –

and we keep revisiting these issues

partly because there is not
a fundamental agreement,

in fact there’s a schism

between what the developed
countries believe and want

and what emerging market countries want.

Emerging market countries need
to continue to create economic growth

so that we don’t have political
uncertainty in the those countries.

Developed countries recognize

that they have a real,
important responsibility

not only just to manage
their CO2 emissions

and some of the degradation
that they’re contributing to the world,

but also as trendsetters in R&D.

And so they have to come
to the table as well.

But in essence, it cannot be a situation

where we start ascribing policies
to the emerging markets

without developed countries themselves

also taking quite a swipe
at what they’re doing

both in demand and supply
in developed markets.

BG: Dambisa, thank you for coming to TED.
DM: Thank you very much.

(Applause)

我们创造
和维持经济增长的能力

是我们这个时代的决定性挑战。

当然还有其他挑战——

医疗保健、疾病负担
和流行病、

环境挑战

,当然还有激进的恐怖主义。

然而,

就我们能够真正
解决经济增长挑战的程度而言,要解决我刚刚阐明的挑战,

我们还需要很长的路要走

更重要的是,

除非并且直到我们解决经济增长问题

并创造可持续
的长期经济增长,否则

我们将无法应对当今继续遍布全球

的看似棘手的挑战

无论是医疗保健、
教育还是经济发展。

根本问题是:

在美国和整个欧洲等发达和发达经济体

在金融危机后继续努力创造经济增长的时候,我们将

如何创造经济增长

它们继续表现不佳,

并且看到经济增长的三个
关键驱动因素:

资本、劳动力和生产力受到侵蚀。

特别是,

这些发达经济体
继续出现债务和赤字,

劳动力质量和数量的下降和侵蚀,

它们还看到生产力停滞不前。

同样,

我们如何
在新兴市场创造经济增长,

那里有 90%
的世界人口

居住,平均

70% 的人口
年龄在 25 岁以下?

在这些国家

,它们必须
以每年至少 7% 的速度增长

,以减少贫困并使一代

人的人均收入翻一番

然而今天

,最大的新兴经济体——

至少拥有
5000 万人口的国家——

仍在努力
达到 7% 的神奇指标。

更糟糕的是,

印度、俄罗斯、
南非、巴西甚至中国等国家的数字


低于 7%,

而且在许多情况下实际上还在倒退。

经济增长很重要。

随着经济增长,

国家和社会
进入

向上流动、机会
和生活水平提高的良性循环。

没有增长,
国家就会收缩和萎缩,

不仅在
经济统计年鉴上,

而且在生活的意义
和生活的方式上。

经济增长
对个人来说非常重要。

如果增长减弱,

人类

进步的风险以及政治
和社会不稳定的风险就会上升

,社会就会变得更加暗淡、
粗糙和缩小。

上下文很重要。

新兴市场国家

不需要以
与发达国家相同的速度增长。

现在,我知道在座的一些人
认为这是一个冒险的提议。

这里有些

人会
转过身来,

对世界各地发生的事情

大失所望,基本上将其
归咎于经济增长。

你担心
地球人口过剩。

看看联合国
最近的统计数据和预测

在 2100 年达到稳定之前,地球上将有 110 亿人,

你会担心这
对自然资源的影响——

耕地、饮用水、
能源和矿产。

您还担心
环境的恶化。

你会担心,

体现在企业全球主义

者身上的人是如何变得贪婪和腐败的。

但我今天在这里告诉你们
,经济增长

一直是

世界各地数百万人生活水平变化的支柱。

更重要


是,资本主义推动的不仅仅是经济增长。

资本主义的定义
很简单,

就是生产要素,

如贸易和工业、
资本和劳动力,


掌握在私营部门而不是国家手中。

这里真的很重要的是
,我们要明白

,从根本上说,批评
不是针对经济增长本身,

而是针对资本主义发生的事情。

就我们需要创造
长期经济增长而言,

我们将不得不
以更好的经济立场来追求它。

经济增长需要资本主义,

但它需要它正常运转。

正如我刚才提到的,

资本主义制度的核心
是由私人行为者定义的。

然而,即便如此,这
也是一种非常简单的二分法。

资本主义:好; 非资本主义:不好。

在实践经验中,

资本主义更像是一个光谱。

我们有像中国

这样实行
更多国家资本主义的

国家,也有
像美国

这样更加市场资本主义的国家。

然而,我们批评资本主义制度的努力

往往集中
在像中国

这样的国家,这些国家实际上
并不是公然的市场资本主义。

然而,

我们现在将注意力
集中在更纯粹的资本主义形式上,

尤其是美国所体现
的资本主义形式,是有真正的理由和真正的担忧的。

这一点非常重要,

因为这种类型的

资本主义越来越多地
受到批评

,即它现在正在助长腐败

,更糟糕的是,

它正在加剧收入不平等——

这种想法是少数人
以牺牲多数人为代价而受益。 我们需要解决

的两个真正关键的问题
是,我们

如何才能修复资本主义,

以便它可以帮助创造经济增长

,同时也
可以帮助解决社会弊病。

为了思考这个框架,
我们必须问自己,

今天的资本主义是如何运作的?

非常简单地说,

资本主义是建立在
个人效用最大化者的基础上的——

一个
追求自己想要的东西的自私个人。

只有在他们
最大化他们的效用之后,

他们才会决定

为其他社会契约提供支持是很重要的。

当然,在这个系统中,
政府会征税,

并使用部分收入
来资助社会项目,他们

认识到政府的
角色不仅是监管,

而且是社会产品的仲裁者。

但是,尽管如此,

这个框架——

这个两阶段的框架——

是我们现在必须

开始思考如何
改进资本主义模式的基础。

我认为
这个挑战有两个方面。

首先,

我们可以借鉴右翼政策

,看看有什么可以让

我们思考
如何改进资本主义。

特别是,

右倾政策

往往侧重于
有条件的转移支付等事情,在这种情况下,

我们支付和奖励
人们做

我们实际上
认为有助于促进经济增长的事情。

例如,

送孩子上学,

父母可以为此赚钱,

或者让他们的孩子
接种或免疫,

父母可以为此获得报酬。

现在,除了

关于
我们是否应该付钱让

人们做我们认为他们应该做

的事情的争论之外,
事实上,按绩效付费

实际上已经

在墨西哥、巴西和巴西等地产生了一些积极的结果。

也在纽约的试点项目中。

但左倾政策也有好处

和重大变化

认为政府应该
扩大其作用和责任

,使其不再被狭隘地界定

,政府应该
更多地成为

生产要素的仲裁者的论点,

在中国的成功中已经司空见惯。

但我们也开始就

私营部门的角色应该如何

摆脱单纯的利润动机

而真正更多地
参与社会项目的交付展开辩论。

诸如企业社会责任计划之类的事情

尽管规模很小,但

正朝着正确的方向发展。

当然,左倾政策
也倾向于模糊

政府、
非政府组织和私营部门之间的界限。

这方面的两个很好的例子
是 19 世纪的美国,

当时基础设施的

推出实际上是关于
公私伙伴关系。

当然,最近,

互联网的
出现也向世界

证明了公共和私人可以
为改善社会而共同努力。

我要给你的基本信息是:

我们不能继续试图通过教条和不必要的意识形态来
解决世界经济增长的挑战

为了创造可持续的、
长期的经济增长

并解决当今继续困扰世界的挑战和社会弊病

我们必须对可行的方法有
更广阔的

视野。

最终,

我们必须认识
到意识形态是增长的敌人。

谢谢你。

(掌声)

Bruno Giussani:我
想问几个问题,Dambisa,

因为人们可以
对你最后

一句话的反应是,增长也是一种意识形态,

它可能
是我们这个时代的主导意识形态。


对那些有这种反应的人说什么?

DM:嗯,我认为这是
完全合法的,

而且我认为我们
已经在进行讨论。

围绕幸福感

和其他
用于衡量人们成功

和生活水平提高的指标进行了大量工作。

因此,我认为我们应该

对可以
提高人们生活水平

并继续减少
世界各地贫困的事物持开放态度。

BG:所以你基本上是在
恳求恢复增长,

但在

不损害
地球容量的情况下

,让我们踏上漫长旅程的唯一方法

是让经济增长

以某种方式与
资源的潜在使用脱钩。

你看到这种情况发生了吗?

DM:嗯,我认为我更
看好人类的能力和独创性。

我认为,如果我们开始限制自己

使用我们今天所知道的有限、稀缺
和枯竭的资源

我们可能会对世界的

现状感到非常消极和
担忧。

然而,我们已经看到了罗马俱乐部,

我们已经看到了以前

声称世界将
耗尽资源

的说法
,并不是说这些事情是无效的。

但我认为,凭借独创性,
我们可以看到海水淡化,

我认为我们可以对能源进行再投资,

这样我们才能真正
获得更好的结果。

所以从这个意义上说,

我对
人类能做的事情更加乐观。

BG:

关于你
关于恢复增长

和采取不同方向

的建议,让我印象深刻的是,你有点建议
用更多的资本主义来修复资本主义——

给良好的行为贴上价格标签作为激励

或发挥更大的
作用 在社会问题上的业务。

这就是你的建议吗?

DM:我建议
我们必须思想开放。

认为传统的经济增长模式

并没有按照
我们希望的方式运作,这绝对是事实。

我认为今天世界

上最大的
经济体美国

拥有民主、

自由民主,
因为它是核心政治立场

,它拥有自由市场资本主义——

在它是自由的范围内——

自由市场资本主义,这绝非偶然
作为其经济立场。

第二大经济体是中国。

它取消了民主的优先地位

,并拥有国家资本主义,
这是一种完全不同的模式。

这两个国家,
完全不同的政治模式

和完全不同的经济模式

,却有着

相同的以基尼系数衡量的收入不平等数字。

我认为这些是
我们应该进行的辩论,

因为我们完全不清楚

我们应该采用哪种模式,

而且我认为需要
更多地

讨论我们所知道的和我们不知道的事情,并且更加谦虚。

BG:最后一个问题。
COP21 正在巴黎举行。

如果你可以给

那里的所有国家
元首和代表团团长发一条推文,

你会说什么?

DM:再一次,我非常愿意
保持开放的态度。

如您所知,

围绕环境问题的问题

已经多次提上议事日程——

在哥本哈根,
72 年在斯德哥尔摩

——我们一直在重新审视这些问题,

部分原因是
没有基本协议

,事实上有一个

发达国家的
信仰和想要

的东西与新兴市场国家想要的东西之间的分裂。

新兴市场国家需要
继续创造经济增长,

这样我们就不会
在这些国家出现政治不确定性。

发达国家认识到

,他们肩负着真正
重要的责任,

不仅要管理
其二氧化碳排放

和它们对世界造成的一些退化

而且还要成为研发的潮流引领者。

所以他们也必须
坐到谈判桌前。

但从本质上讲,如果没有发达国家自己也对他们在发达市场的供需两方面所做的事情

进行相当大的打击,我们就不会开始将政策
归咎于新兴

市场。

BG:Dambisa,感谢您来到 TED。
DM:非常感谢。

(掌声)