How baby bonds could help close the wealth gap Darrick Hamilton

There is a narrative,

an idea that with resilience,
grit and personal responsibility

people can pull themselves up
and achieve economic success.

In the United States
we call it the American dream.

A similar narrative
exists all over the world.

But the truth is that the challenges
of making this happen

have less to do with what we do

and more to do with the wealth position
in which we are born.

So I’m going to make the case
that the United States government,

actually that any government,

should create a trust account
for every newborn

of up to 60,000 dollars,

calibrated to the wealth
of the family in which they are born.

I’m talking about an endowment.

Personal seed capital,
a publicly established baby trust,

what my colleague William Darity
at Duke University and I

have referred to as baby bonds,

a term that was coined by the late
historian from Columbia University,

Manning Marable.

The reason why we should create
these trusts is simple.

Wealth is the paramount indicator
of economic security and well-being.

It provides financial agency,
economic security to take risk

and shield against loss.

Without capital, inequality is locked in.

We use words like choice, freedom
to describe the benefits of the market,

but it is literally wealth that gives us
choice, freedom and optionality.

Wealthier families are better positioned
to finance an elite, independent school

and college education,

access capital to start a business,

finance expensive medical procedures,

reside in neighborhoods
with higher amenities,

exert political influence
through campaign finance,

purchase better legal counsel

if confronted with an expensive
criminal justice system,

leave a bequest

and/or withstand financial hardship
resulting from any number of emergencies.

Basically, when it comes
to economic security,

wealth is both the beginning and the end.

I will frame this conversation
in the context of the United States,

but this discussion
applies virtually to any country

facing increasing inequality.

In the US, the top
10 percent of households

hold about 80 percent
of the nation’s wealth

while the bottom 60 percent
owns only about one percent.

But when it comes to wealth,

race is an even stronger predictor
than class itself.

Blacks and Latinos collectively
make up 30 percent

of the United States population,

but collectively own about seven percent
of the nation’s wealth.

The 2016 survey of consumer finance

indicates that the typical black family
has about 17,000 dollars in wealth,

and that’s inclusive of home equity,

while the typical white family
has about 170,000.

That is indicative
of an absolute racial wealth gap

where the typical black household
has about 10 cents for every dollar

held by the typical white family.

But regardless of race,

the market alone has been inadequate
to address these inequalities.

Even in times of economic
expansion, inequality grows.

Over the last 45 years,

wealth disparity
has increased dramatically,

and essentially, all the economic gains
from America’s increase in productivity

have gone to the elite
or the upper middle class.

Yet, much of the framing
around economic disparity

focuses on the poor choices

of black, Latino and poor borrowers.

This framing is wrong.

The directional emphasis is wrong.

It is more likely that meager
economic circumstance,

not poor decision making
or deficient knowledge,

constrains choice itself
and leaves people with no options

but to turn to predatory finance.

In essence, education
is not the magic antidote

for the enormous inherited disparities

that result from laws,
policies and economic arrangement.

This does not diminish
the value of education.

Indeed, I’m a university professor.

There are clear
intrinsic values to education,

along with a public responsibility

to expose everyone
to a high-quality education,

from grade school
all the way through college.

But education is not the panacea.

In fact, blacks who live in families
where the head graduated from college

typically have less wealth

than white families
where the head dropped out of high school.

Perhaps we overstate
the functional role of education

at the detriment of understanding
the functional role of wealth.

Basically, it is wealth
that begets more wealth.

That’s why we advocate for baby trust.

An economic birthright
to capital for everyone.

These accounts
would be held in public trust

to be used as a foundation
to an economically secure life.

The concept of economic rights
is not new nor is it radical.

In 1944, President Franklin Roosevelt

introduced the idea
of an economic Bill of Rights.

Roosevelt called for physical security,

economic security,
social security and moral security.

Unfortunately, since
the Nixon administration,

the political sentiment
regarding social mobility

has radically shifted away from
government mandates to economic security

to a neoliberal approach

in which the market is presumed
to be the solution for all our problems,

economic or otherwise.

As a result, the onus of social mobility
has shifted on to the individual.

The pervasive narrative is
that even if your lot in life is subpar,

with perseverance and hard work
and the virtues of the free market,

you can turn your
proverbial rags into riches.

Of course, the flip side
is that the virtues of the market

will likewise sanction those
that are not astute,

those that lack motivation
or those that are simply lazy.

In other words, the deserving poor
will receive their just rewards.

What is glaringly missing
from this narrative

is the role of power and capital,

and how that power and capital

can be used to alter the rules
and structure of transactions and markets

in the first place.

Power and capital become self-reinforcing.

And without government intervention,

they generate an iterative cycle
of both stratification and inequality.

The capital finance provided by baby trust

is intended to deliver a more
egalitarian and an authentic pathway

to economic security,

independent of the family
financial position

in which individuals are born.

The program would complement
the economic rights to old-age pensions

and provide a more comprehensive
social security program,

designed to provide capital finance
from cradle all the way through grave.

We envision endowing American newborns
with an average account of 25,000 dollars

that gradually rises
upwards to 60,000 dollars

for babies born into the poorest families.

Babies born into the wealthiest families

would be included as well
in the social contract,

but they would receive a more
nominal account of about 500 dollars.

The accounts would be federally managed,

and they would grow at a guaranteed
annual interest rate

of about two percent per year
in order to curtail inflation cost,

and be used when the child
reaches adulthood

for some asset-enhancing activity,

like financing a debt-free
university education,

a down payment to purchase a home,

or some seed capital to start a business.

With approximately four million babies
born each year in the US,

if the average endowment of a baby trust
is set at 25,000 dollars,

the program would crudely cost
about 100 billion dollars a year.

This would constitute

only about two percent
of current federal expenditures

and be far less than
the 500-plus billion dollars

that’s already being spent
by the federal government

on asset promotion
through tax credits and subsidies.

At issue is not the amount
of that allocation

but to whom it’s distributed.

Currently, the top
one percent of households,

those earning above 100 million dollars,

receive only about one third
of this entire allocation,

while the bottom 60 percent
receive only five percent.

If the federal asset-promoting budget

were allocated
in a more progressive manner,

federal policies could be
transformative for all Americans.

This is a work in progress.

There are obviously many details
to be worked out,

but it is a policy proposal
grounded in the functional roles

and the inherited advantages of wealth

that moves us away
from the reinforcing status quo

behavioral explanations for inequality

towards more structural solutions.

Our existing tax policy
that privileges existing wealth

rather than establishing
new wealth is a choice.

The extent of our dramatic inequality
is at least as much a problem of politics

as it is a problem of economics.

It is time to get beyond
the false narratives

that attribute inequality
to individual personal deficits

while largely ignoring
the advantages of wealth.

Instead, public provisions of a baby trust

could go a long way towards eliminating

the transmission of economic advantage
or disadvantage across generations

and establishing a more moral
and decent economy

that facilitates assets, economic security

and social mobility for all its citizens.

Regardless of the race

and the family positions
in which they are born.

Thank you very much.

(Applause)

Chris Anderson: Darrick.

I mean, there’s so much
to like in this idea.

There’s one piece of branding around it
that I worry about,

which is just that right now,
trust-fund kids have a really bad rap.

You know, they’re the sort of
eyeball-rolling poster children

for how money, kind of,
takes away motivation.

So, these trusts are different.

So how do you show people in this proposal
that it’s not going to do that?

Darrick Hamilton: If you know
you have limited resources

or you’re going to face discrimination,

there’s a narrative that, well,

the economic returns
to investing in myself

are lower than that of someone else,

so I might as well enjoy my leisure.

Of course, there’s another
narrative as well,

so we shouldn’t get caught up on that,

you know, somebody who’s poor
and going to face discrimination,

they also might pursue
a resume-building strategy.

The old adage, “I have to be
twice as good as someone else.”

Now, when we say that,
we never ask at what cost,

are there health costs
associated with that.

I haven’t answered your question,
but coming back to you question,

if you know you’re going to receive
a transfer at a later point in life,

that only increases the incentive
for you to invest in yourself

so that you can better use that trust.

CA: You’re giving people
possibilities of life

they currently cannot imagine having.

And therefore the motivation to do that.

I could talk with you
for hours about this.

I’m really glad you’re working on this.

Thank you.

(Applause)

有一种说法,

一种想法是,具有韧性、
勇气和个人责任感的

人可以振作起来
并取得经济上的成功。

在美国,
我们称之为美国梦。

世界各地都有类似的说法。

但事实是,
实现这一目标的挑战

与我们所做的事情关系不大,而与

我们出生时所处的财富地位有关。

所以我要
说明的是,美国政府,

实际上是任何政府,

都应该
为每个

新生儿创建一个高达 60,000 美元的信托账户,

并根据他们出生的家庭的财富进行校准。

我说的是禀赋。

个人种子资本,
一个公开建立的婴儿信托基金,

我和杜克大学的同事威廉·达里蒂(William Darity)

将其称为婴儿债券,

这个词是
由哥伦比亚大学已故历史学家

曼宁·马布尔创造的。

我们应该创建
这些信任的原因很简单。

财富
是经济安全和福祉的最重要指标。

它为承担风险和抵御损失提供金融机构、
经济保障

没有资本,不平等就被锁定了。

我们用选择、自由等词
来描述市场的好处,

但实际上是财富给了我们
选择、自由和选择权。

较富裕的家庭更有能力
为精英、独立学校

和大学教育

提供资金、获得创业资金、

为昂贵的医疗程序提供资金、

居住在
便利设施更好的社区、

通过竞选资金施加政治影响、在面临

困难时购买更好的法律顾问

昂贵的
刑事司法系统,

留下遗赠

和/或承受
任何数量的紧急情况造成的经济困难。

基本上,
就经济安全而言,

财富既是起点也是终点。

我将
在美国的背景下构建这个对话,

但这个讨论
实际上适用于任何

面临日益加剧的不平等的国家。

在美国,前
10% 的家庭

拥有全国 80%
的财富,

而底层 60% 的家庭
只拥有约 1% 的财富。

但在财富方面,

种族
比阶级本身更能预测。

黑人和拉丁裔共同

占美国人口的 30%,

但共同拥有该国约 7%
的财富。

2016年的消费金融调查

显示,典型的黑人家庭
拥有大约17,000美元的财富

,其中包括房屋净值,

而典型的白人
家庭大约有170,000美元。


表明存在绝对的种族贫富差距

,典型的白人家庭
每持有 1 美元,典型的黑人家庭就有 10 美分

但无论种族如何

,仅靠市场
不足以解决这些不平等问题。

即使在经济
扩张时期,不平等也会加剧。

在过去的 45 年里,

贫富差距
急剧扩大

,基本上,美国生产力提高带来的所有经济收益

都流向了精英
或中上阶层。

然而,
围绕经济差距的大部分框架都

集中在

黑人、拉丁裔和贫困借款人的糟糕选择上。

这个框架是错误的。

方向强调是错误的。

更有可能的是,微薄的
经济环境,

而不是糟糕的决策
或缺乏知识,

限制了选择本身
,让人们

别无选择,只能求助于掠夺性金融。

从本质上讲,
教育并不是解决

法律、
政策和经济安排造成的巨大遗传差异的灵丹妙药。

这并没有
降低教育的价值。

确实,我是大学教授。 教育

有明确的
内在价值,

以及从小学一直

到大学让每个人都
接受高质量教育的公共责任

但教育不是灵丹妙药。

事实上,住在
校长大学毕业的家庭中的黑人

通常


高中辍学的白人家庭拥有更少的财富。

也许我们夸大
了教育的功能性作用,

而不利于理解
财富的功能性作用。

基本上,财富
会产生更多的财富。

这就是为什么我们提倡婴儿信任。

每个人都拥有资本的经济与生俱来的权利。

这些账户
将由公众信托持有,

作为经济安全生活的基础。

经济权利的概念
并不新鲜,也不是激进的。

1944 年,富兰克林·罗斯福总统

提出了经济权利法案的概念。

罗斯福呼吁物理安全、

经济安全、
社会安全和道德安全。

不幸的是,
自尼克松政府以来,

关于社会流动性的政治情绪

已经从
政府授权转向经济安全,

转向新自由主义方法,

在这种方法中,市场被
认为是解决我们所有问题的方法,

无论是经济问题还是其他问题。

结果,社会流动的责任
转移到了个人身上。

普遍的说法是
,即使你的生活状况不佳,只要

有毅力和努力工作
以及自由市场的美德,

你也可以把你
众所周知的破烂变成财富。

当然,
另一方面,市场的

好处同样会制裁
那些不精明

、缺乏动力
或只是懒惰的人。

换句话说,应得的穷人
将得到他们应得的回报。

这种叙述中明显缺失的

是权力和资本的作用,

以及如何利用这种权力和

资本首先改变
交易和市场的规则和结构

权力和资本会自我强化。

在没有政府干预的情况下,

它们会产生
分层和不平等的迭代循环。

婴儿信托提供的资本融资

旨在提供一种更加
平等和真实的

经济安全途径,

独立于个人出生的家庭
财务状况

该计划将补充
养老金的经济权利,

并提供更全面的
社会保障计划,

旨在提供
从摇篮到坟墓的资本融资。

我们设想为美国新生儿
提供 25,000 美元的平均账户资金

,然后逐渐
增加到

最贫困家庭出生的婴儿的 60,000 美元。

出生在最富裕家庭的婴儿

也将被
纳入社会契约,

但他们将获得
约 500 美元的名义账户。

这些账户将由联邦政府管理

,它们将以
每年

约 2% 的保证年利率增长
,以降低通货膨胀成本,

并在孩子
成年时

用于某些资产增强活动,

例如为债务融资—— 免费
大学教育,

购买房屋的首付,

或一些创业资金。

美国每年大约有 400 万婴儿
出生,

如果将婴儿信托基金的平均捐赠额定
为 25,000 美元,

那么该计划
每年的费用大约为 1000 亿美元。

这仅占

当前联邦支出的 2% 左右

,远低于

联邦政府

通过税收抵免和补贴用于资产促销的 500 多亿美元。

问题不是
分配的数量,

而是分配给谁。

目前

,收入在 1 亿美元以上的

收入最高的 1% 家庭仅获得
全部分配的三分之一左右,

而最低 60% 的家庭
仅获得 5%。

如果

以更渐进的方式分配联邦资产促进预算,

联邦政策可能
对所有美国人产生变革性影响。

这是一项正在进行的工作。

显然有许多
细节需要解决,

但这是一项
基于功能性角色

和财富继承优势的政策

建议,使我们
摆脱了

对不平等现象的强化现状行为解释,

转向更具结构性的解决方案。

我们现有的税收政策
赋予现有财富特权

而不是建立
新财富是一种选择。

我们戏剧性的不平等
程度至少与

经济问题一样是政治问题。

是时候摆脱

那些将不平等
归因于个人缺陷

而在很大程度上
忽视财富优势的虚假叙述了。

相反,婴儿信托的公共规定

可以大大有助于

消除经济优势
或劣势代际传递,

并建立一个更加道德
和体面的经济

,促进

其所有公民的资产、经济安全和社会流动。

无论他们出生的种族

和家庭
地位如何。

非常感谢你。

(掌声)

克里斯·安德森:达里克。

我的意思是,
这个想法有很多值得喜欢的地方。 我担心

它周围有一个品牌

那就是现在,
信托基金的孩子们的名声非常糟糕。

你知道,他们是那种
让人眼花缭乱的海报孩子

,因为金钱是如何
带走动力的。

所以,这些信托是不同的。

那么你如何在这个提案中向人们
表明它不会那样做呢?

达里克汉密尔顿:如果你知道
自己的资源有限,

或者你将面临歧视,

那么有一种说法是,

投资自己

的经济回报比别人低,

所以我不妨享受我的闲暇时光。

当然,还有另一种
说法,

所以我们不应该被赶上那个,

你知道,一个贫穷的人
会面临歧视,

他们也可能会追求
建立简历的策略。

古老的格言,“我必须是
别人的两倍。”

现在,当我们这么说时,
我们从不问代价是什么,

是否有
与此相关的健康成本。

我没有回答你的问题,
但回到你的问题,

如果你知道你
将在以后的生活中收到转移

,那只会增加
你投资自己的动力,

这样你就可以更好地利用 那种信任。

CA:你为人们
提供了

他们目前无法想象的生活可能性。

因此,这样做的动机。

我可以和你
谈几个小时。

我真的很高兴你在做这件事。

谢谢你。

(掌声)