What is economic value and who creates it Mariana Mazzucato

Value creation.

Wealth creation.

These are really powerful words.

Maybe you think of finance,
you think of innovation,

you think of creativity.

But who are the value creators?

If we use that word, we must be implying
that some people aren’t creating value.

Who are they?

The couch potatoes?

The value extractors?

The value destroyers?

To answer this question, we actually
have to have a proper theory of value.

And I’m here as an economist
to break it to you

that we’ve kind of lost our way
on this question.

Now, don’t look so surprised.

What I mean by that is,
we’ve stopped contesting it.

We’ve stopped actually asking
really tough questions

about what is the difference between
value creation and value extraction,

productive and unproductive activities.

Now, let me just give you
some context here.

2009 was just about
a year and a half after

one of the biggest
financial crises of our time,

second only to the 1929 Great Depression,

and the CEO of Goldman Sachs said

Goldman Sachs workers are the most
productive in the world.

Productivity and productiveness,
for an economist,

actually has a lot to do with value.

You’re producing stuff,

you’re producing it
dynamically and efficiently.

You’re also producing things
that the world needs, wants and buys.

Now, how this could have been said
just one year after the crisis,

which actually had this bank
as well as many other banks –

I’m just kind of picking
on Goldman Sachs here –

at the center of the crisis, because
they had actually produced

some pretty problematic financial products
mainly but not only related to mortgages,

which saw many thousands of people
actually lose their homes.

In 2010, in just one month, September,

120,000 people lost their homes
through the foreclosures of that crisis.

Between 2007 and 2010,

8.8 million people lost their jobs.

The bank also had to then
be bailed out by the US taxpayer

for the sum of 10 billion dollars.

We didn’t hear the taxpayers bragging
that they were value creators,

but obviously, having bailed out

one of the biggest value-creating
productive companies,

perhaps they should have.

What I want to do next
is kind of ask ourselves

how we lost our way,

how it could be, actually,

that a statement like that
could almost go unnoticed,

because it wasn’t an after-dinner joke;
it was said very seriously.

So what I want to do is bring you back
300 years in economic thinking,

when, actually, the term was contested.

It doesn’t mean that
they were right or wrong,

but you couldn’t just call yourself
a value creator, a wealth creator.

There was a lot of debate
within the economics profession.

And what I want to argue is,
we’ve kind of lost our way,

and that has actually allowed this term,
“wealth creation” and “value,”

to become quite weak and lazy

and also easily captured.

OK? So let’s start –
I hate to break it to you –

300 years ago.

Now, what was interesting 300 years ago

is the society was still
an agricultural type of society.

So it’s not surprising
that the economists of the time,

who were called the Physiocrats,

actually put the center
of their attention to farm labor.

When they said, “Where
does value come from?”

they looked at farming.

And they produced what I think was
probably the world’s first spreadsheet,

called the “Tableau Economique,”

and this was done by François Quesnay,
one of the leaders of this movement.

And it was very interesting,

because they didn’t just say,
“Farming is the source of value.”

They then really worried about
what was happening to that value

when it was produced.

What the Tableau Economique does –

and I’ve tried to make it
a bit simpler here for you –

is it broke down the classes
in society into three.

The farmers, creating value,
were called the “productive class.”

Then others who were just
moving some of this value around

but it was useful, it was necessary,

these were the merchants;

they were called the “proprietors.”

And then there was another class
that was simply charging the farmers a fee

for an existing asset, the land,

and they called them the “sterile class.”

Now, this is a really heavy-hitting word
if you think what it means:

that if too much of the resources
are going to the landlords,

you’re actually putting the reproduction
potential of the system at risk.

And so all these little arrows there
were their way of simulating –

again, spreadsheets and simulators,
these guys were really using big data –

they were simulating what would
actually happen under different scenarios

if the wealth actually wasn’t
reinvested back into production

to make that land more productive

and was actually being
siphoned out in different ways,

or even if the proprietors
were getting too much.

And what later happened in the 1800s,

and this was no longer
the Agricultural Revolution

but the Industrial Revolution,

is that the classical economists,

and these were Adam Smith, David Ricardo,
Karl Marx, the revolutionary,

also asked the question “What is value?”

But it’s not surprising that
because they were actually living

through an industrial era
with the rise of machines and factories,

they said it was industrial labor.

So they had a labor theory of value.

But again, their focus was reproduction,

this real worry of what was happening
to the value that was created

if it was getting siphoned out.

And in “The Wealth of Nations,”

Adam Smith had this really great example
of the pin factory where he said

if you only have one person
making every bit of the pin,

at most you can make one pin a day.

But if you actually invest in factory
production and the division of labor,

new thinking –

today, we would use the word
“organizational innovation” –

then you could increase the productivity

and the growth and the wealth of nations.

So he showed that 10 specialized workers

who had been invested in,
in their human capital,

could produce 4,800 pins a day,

as opposed to just one
by an unspecialized worker.

And he and his fellow classical economists

also broke down activities
into productive and unproductive ones.

(Laughter)

And the unproductive ones weren’t –

I think you’re laughing because
most of you are on that list, aren’t you?

(Laughter)

Lawyers! I think he was right
about the lawyers.

Definitely not the professors,
the letters of all kind people.

So lawyers, professors,
shopkeepers, musicians.

He obviously hated the opera.

He must have seen
the worst performance of his life

the night before writing this book.

There’s at least
three professions up there

that have to do with the opera.

But this wasn’t an exercise
of saying, “Don’t do these things.”

It was just, “What’s going to happen

if we actually end up allowing
some parts of the economy to get too large

without really thinking about
how to increase the productivity

of the source of the value
that they thought was key,

which was industrial labor.

And again, don’t ask yourself
is this right or is this wrong,

it was just very contested.

By making these lists,

it actually forced them also
to ask interesting questions.

And their focus,
as the focus of the Physiocrats,

was, in fact, on these objective
conditions of production.

They also looked, for example,
at the class struggle.

Their understanding of wages

had to do with the objective,
if you want, power relationships,

the bargaining power of capital and labor.

But again, factories, machines,
division of labor,

agricultural land
and what was happening to it.

So the big revolution
that then happened –

and this, by the way, is not often
taught in economics classes –

the big revolution that happened
with the current system

of economic thinking that we have,

which is called “neoclassical economics,”

was that the logic completely changed.

It changed in two ways.

It changed from this focus on
objective conditions to subjective ones.

Let me explain what I mean by that.

Objective, in the way I just said.

Subjective, in the sense that
all the attention went to

how individuals of different sorts
make their decisions.

OK, so workers are maximizing
their choices of leisure versus work.

Consumers are maximizing
their so-called utility,

which is a proxy for happiness,

and firms are maximizing their profits.

And the idea behind this was that
then we can aggregate this up,

and we see what that turns into,

which are these nice, fancy
supply-and-demand curves

which produce a price,

an equilibrium price.

It’s an equilibrium price,
because we also added to it

a lot of Newtonian physics equations

where centers of gravity are very much
part of the organizing principle.

But the second point here is that
that equilibrium price, or prices,

reveal value.

So the revolution here is a change
from objective to subjective,

but also the logic is no longer
one of what is value,

how is it being determined,

what is the reproductive
potential of the economy,

which then leads to a theory of price

but rather the reverse:

a theory of price and exchange

which reveals value.

Now, this is a huge change.

And it’s not just an academic exercise,
as fascinating as that might be.

It affects how we measure growth.

It affects how we steer economies
to produce more of some activities,

less of others,

how we also remunerate
some activities more than others.

And it also just kind of makes you think,

you know, are you happy to get out of bed
if you’re a value creator or not,

and how is the price system itself
if you aren’t determining that?

I mentioned it affects
how we think about output.

If we only include, for example, in GDP,

those activities that have prices,

all sorts of really weird things happen.

Feminist economists
and environmental economists

have actually written
about this quite a bit.

Let me give you some examples.

If you marry your babysitter,
GDP will go down, so do not do it.

Do not be tempted to do this, OK?

Because an activity that perhaps was
before being paid for is still being done

but is no longer paid.

(Laughter)

If you pollute, GDP goes up.

Still don’t do it, but if you do it,
you’ll help the economy.

Why? Because we have to actually
pay someone to clean it.

Now, what’s also really interesting
is what happened to finance

in the financial sector in GDP.

This also, by the way, is something
I’m always surprised

that many economists don’t know.

Up until 1970,

most of the financial sector
was not even included in GDP.

It was kind of indirectly,
perhaps not knowingly,

still being seen through the eyes
of the Physiocrats

as just kind of moving stuff around,
not actually producing anything new.

So only those activities
that had an explicit price were included.

For example, if you went to get
a mortgage, you were charged a fee.

That went into GDP and the national
income and product accounting.

But, for example,
net interest payments didn’t,

the difference between
what banks were earning in interest

if they gave you a loan and what
they were paying out for a deposit.

That wasn’t being included.

And so the people doing the accounting
started to look at some data,

which started to show
that the size of finance

and these net interest payments

were actually growing substantially.

And they called this
the “banking problem.”

These were some people working
inside, actually, the United Nations

in a group called the Systems
of National [Accounts], SNA.

They called it the “banking problem,”

like, “Oh my God, this thing is huge,
and we’re not even including it.”

So instead of stopping and actually
making that Tableau Economique

or asking some of these
fundamental questions

that also the classicals were asking
about what is actually happening,

the division of labor between different
types of activities in the economy,

they simply gave these
net interest payments a name.

So the commercial banks, they called this
“financial intermediation.”

That went into the NIPA accounts.

And the investment banks
were called the “risk-taking activities,”

and that went in.

In case I haven’t explained this properly,

that red line is showing how much quicker

financial intermediation
as a whole was growing

compared to the rest of the economy,
the blue line, industry.

And so this was quite extraordinary,

because what actually happened,
and what we know today,

and there’s different people
writing about this,

this data here
is from the Bank of England,

is that lots of what finance
was actually doing

from the 1970s and ’80s on

was basically financing itself:

finance financing finance.

And what I mean by that is finance,
insurance and real estate.

In fact, in the UK,

something like between
10 and 20 percent of finance

finds its way into
the real economy, into industry,

say, into the energy sector,
into pharmaceuticals,

into the IT sector,

but most of it goes back
into that acronym, FIRE:

finance, insurance and real estate.

It’s very conveniently called FIRE.

Now, this is interesting because, in fact,

it’s not to say that finance
is good or bad,

but the degree to which,

by just having to give it a name,

because it actually had an income
that was being generated,

as opposed to pausing and asking,
“What is it actually doing?” –

that was a missed opportunity.

Similarly, in the real economy,
in industry itself, what was happening?

And this real focus on prices
and also share prices

has created a huge problem
of reinvestment,

again, this real attention that both
the Physiocrats and the classicals had

to the degree to which the value
that was being generated in the economy

was in fact being reinvested back in.

And so what we have today is
an ultrafinancialized industrial sector

where, increasingly, a share
of the profits and the net income

are not actually going
back into production,

into human capital training,
into research and development

but just being siphoned out
in terms of buying back your own shares,

which boosts stock options,
which is, in fact, the way

that many executives are getting paid.

And, you know, some
share buybacks is absolutely fine,

but this system
is completely out of whack.

These numbers that I’m showing you here

show that in the last 10 years,
466 of the S and P 500 companies

have spent over four trillion
on just buying back their shares.

And what you see then if you aggregate
this up at the macroeconomic level,

so if we look at aggregate
business investment,

which is a percentage of GDP,

you also see this falling level
of business investment.

And this is a problem.

This, by the way, is a huge problem
for skills and job creation.

You might have heard there’s lots
of attention these days

to, “Are the robots taking our jobs?”

Well, mechanization has
for centuries, actually, taken jobs,

but as long as profits were being
reinvested back into production,

then it didn’t matter: new jobs appeared.

But this lack of reinvestment
is, in fact, very dangerous.

Similarly, in the pharmaceutical industry,
for example, how prices are set,

it’s quite interesting how it doesn’t look
at these objective conditions

of the collective way in which value
is created in the economy.

So in the sector where you have
lots of different actors –

public, private, of course, but also
third-sector organizations –

creating value,

the way we actually measure
value in this sector

is through the price system itself.

Prices reveal value.

So when, recently,

the price of an antibiotic
went up by 400 percent overnight,

and the CEO was asked,
“How can you do this?

People actually need that antibiotic.

That’s unfair.”

He said, “Well, we have a moral imperative

to allow prices to go
what the market will bear,”

completely dismissing the fact
that in the US, for example,

the National Institutes of Health
spent over 30 billion a year

on the medical research
that actually leads to these drugs.

So, again, a lack of attention
to those objective conditions

and just allowing the price system
itself to reveal the value.

Now, this is not just
an academic exercise,

as interesting as it may be.

All this really matters
[for] how we measure output,

to how we steer the economy,

to whether you feel
that you’re productive,

to which sectors we end up
helping, supporting

and also making people feel
proud to be part of.

In fact, going back to that quote,

it’s not surprising that Blankfein
could say that.

He was right.

In the way that we actually measure
production, productivity

and value in the economy,

of course Goldman Sachs workers
are the most productive.

They are in fact earning the most.

The price of their labor
is revealing their value.

But this becomes tautological, of course.

And so there’s a real need to rethink.

We need to rethink
how we’re measuring output,

and in fact there’s some
amazing experiments worldwide.

In New Zealand, for example, they now have
a gross national happiness indicator.

In Bhutan, also, they’re thinking
about happiness and well-being indicators.

But the problem is that we can’t
just be adding things in.

We do have to pause,

and I think this should be
a moment for pause,

given that we see so little
has actually changed

since the financial crisis,

to make sure that
we are not also confusing

value extraction with value creation,

so looking at what’s included,
not just adding more,

to make sure that we’re not, for example,
confusing rents with profits.

Rents for the classicals
was about unearned income.

Today, rents, when they’re
talked about in economics,

is just an imperfection
towards a competitive price

that could be competed away
if you take away some asymmetries.

Second, we of course can steer
activities into what the classicals called

the “production boundary.”

This should not be an us-versus-them,

big, bad finance versus
good, other sectors.

We could reform finance.

There was a real lost opportunity
in some ways after the crisis.

We could have had
the financial transaction tax,

which would have rewarded
long-termism over short-termism,

but we didn’t decide to do that globally.

We can. We can change our minds.

We can also set up
new types of institutions.

There’s different types of, for example,
public financial institutions worldwide

that are actually providing that patient,
long-term, committed finance

that helps small firms grow, that help
infrastructure and innovation happen.

But this shouldn’t just be about output.

This shouldn’t just be about
the rate of output.

We should also as a society pause

and ask: What value are we even creating?

And I just want to end with the fact
that this week we are celebrating

the 50th anniversary of the Moon landing.

This required the public sector,
the private sector,

to invest and innovate
in all sorts of ways,

not just around aeronautics.

It included investment in areas
like nutrition and materials.

There were lots of actual mistakes
that were done along the way.

In fact, what government did was it used
its full power of procurement,

for example, to fuel
those bottom-up solutions,

of which some failed.

But are failures part of value creation?

Or are they just mistakes?

Or how do we actually also
nurture the experimentation,

the trial and error and error and error?

Bell Labs, which was
the R and D laboratory of AT and T,

actually came from an era
where government was quite courageous.

It actually asked AT and T that
in order to maintain its monopoly status,

it had to reinvest its profits
back into the real economy,

innovation

and innovation beyond telecoms.

That was the history,
the early history of Bell Labs.

So how we can get these new conditions
around reinvestment

to collectively invest
in new types of value

directed at some of the biggest
challenges of our time,

like climate change?

This is a key question.

But we should also ask ourselves,

had there been a net
present value calculation

or a cost-benefit analysis done

about whether or not to even try
to go to the Moon and back again

in a generation,

we probably wouldn’t have started.

So thank God,

because I’m an economist,
and I can tell you,

value is not just price.

Thank you.

(Applause)

创造价值。

财富创造。

这些是非常有力的词。

也许你会想到金融,
你会想到创新,

你会想到创造力。

但谁是价值创造者?

如果我们使用这个词,我们一定是在
暗示有些人没有创造价值。

他们是谁?

沙发土豆?

价值提取者?

价值破坏者?

要回答这个问题,我们实际上
必须有一个正确的价值理论。

我作为一名经济学家在这里
向你打破它

,我们
在这个问题上有点迷失了方向。

现在,不要看起来那么惊讶。

我的意思是,
我们已经停止竞争了。

我们实际上已经停止询问

关于
价值创造和价值提取、

生产性活动和非生产性活动之间有什么区别的非常棘手的问题。

现在,让我在这里给你
一些背景信息。

2009 年距离

我们这个时代最大的金融危机之一仅一年半,

仅次于 1929 年的大萧条

,高盛首席执行官表示,

高盛的员工
是世界上生产力最高的。 对于经济学家来说

,生产力和生产力

实际上与价值有很大关系。

你在生产东西,

你在
动态和高效地生产它。

你也在
生产世界需要、想要和购买的东西。

现在,这怎么能
在危机发生仅仅一年后说出来

,实际上这家银行
以及许多其他银行——

我在
这里有点挑剔高盛——

处于危机的中心,因为
他们 实际上已经生产了

一些非常有问题的金融产品,
主要但不仅仅是与抵押贷款有关,

导致成千上万的人
实际上失去了家园。

2010 年,仅仅一个月,即 9 月,就有

120,000 人因
那场危机的止赎而失去了家园。

2007 年至 2010 年间,有

880 万人失业。

随后,该银行还
不得不接受美国

纳税人的 100 亿美元救助。

我们没有听到纳税人
吹嘘他们是价值创造者,

但显然,他们已经救助

了最大的创造价值的
生产性公司之一,

也许他们应该这样做。

我接下来想做的
是问问自己

,我们是如何迷失

方向的,实际上,

这样的声明
几乎不会被人注意到,

因为这不是饭后玩笑;
说得很认真。

所以我想做的是让你回到
300 年前的经济思想

,实际上,这个词是有争议的。

这并不意味着
他们是对还是错,

但你不能仅仅称自己
为价值创造者、财富创造者。

经济学界有很多争论。

我想说的是,
我们有点迷失了方向

,这实际上让
“财富创造”和“价值

”这个词变得相当软弱和懒惰

,也很容易被抓住。

好的? 所以让我们开始吧——
我不想告诉你

——300 年前。

现在,有趣的

是,300 年前的社会仍然
是农业型社会。

因此

当时被称为重农主义者的经济学家

实际上
将注意力集中在农业劳动上也就不足为奇了。

当他们说:“
价值从何而来?”

他们看着农业。

他们制作了我认为
可能是世界上第一个电子表格,

称为“经济表”

,这是由该运动的领导者之一弗朗索瓦·奎奈(François Quesnay)完成的

这很有趣,

因为他们不只是说,
“农业是价值的源泉。”

然后他们真的很担心
这个值

在产生时会发生什么。

Tableau Economique 所做的

——我试图在
这里为你简化一点

——它将
社会中的阶级分为三个。

创造价值的农民
被称为“生产阶级”。

然后其他人只是在
转移一些价值,

但它是有用的,是必要的,

这些是商人;

他们被称为“业主”。

然后还有另一个阶级
,只是向农民

收取现有资产土地的费用

,他们称他们为“不育阶级”。

现在,如果您认为这是一个非常重要的词,
那么它的含义是

:如果过多的
资源流向了地主,

您实际上是在将系统的再生
潜力置于危险之中。

所以所有这些小箭头都有
他们的模拟方式——

再次,电子表格和模拟器,
这些人真的在使用大数据——

他们模拟的是

如果财富实际上没有
重新投资于生产,在不同情况下实际会发生什么

使这片土地更有生产力

,实际上正在
以不同的方式被抽走,

或者即使所有者
得到了太多。

后来发生在 1800 年代

,这不再
是农业革命,

而是工业革命

,古典经济学家,即

亚当·斯密、大卫·李嘉图、
卡尔·马克思,革命者,

也提出了“什么是价值”的问题 ?”

但这并不奇怪,
因为他们实际上生活

在一个
机器和工厂兴起的工业时代,

他们说这是工业劳动力。

所以他们有劳动价值论。

但同样,他们的重点是再生产

,真正担心如果被抽走
所创造的价值会发生什么

在《国富论》中,

亚当·斯密有一个非常棒
的大头针工厂的例子,他说

如果你只有一个人来
制作每一位大头针

,那么你一天最多只能制作一个大头针。

但如果你真正投资于工厂
生产和劳动分工,

新思维——

今天,我们会使用
“组织创新”这个词——

那么你就可以提高生产力

、国家的增长和财富。

因此,他表明,投入人力资本的 10 名专业工人

每天可以生产 4,800 根针,

而不是
一名非专业工人只能生产一根。

他和他的古典经济学家同事

也将活动
分为生产性活动和非生产性活动。

(笑声)

而那些没有效率的人则没有——

我认为你们在笑是因为
你们中的大多数人都在那个名单上,不是吗?

(笑声)

律师! 我认为他
对律师的看法是正确的。

绝对不是教授,
所有好心人的来信。

所以律师、教授、
店主、音乐家。

他显然讨厌歌剧。 在写这本书的前一天晚上,

他一定已经看到
了他一生中最糟糕的表现

那里至少有
三个

与歌剧有关的职业。

但这不是
说“不要做这些事情”的练习。

只是,“

如果我们最终允许
经济的某些部分变得过大,

而没有真正考虑
如何提高他们认为是关键

的价值来源的生产力,
那会发生什么,

那就是工业劳动力。

再说一次,不要问
自己这是对还是错,

这只是非常有争议。

通过列出这些列表,

实际上也迫使他们
也提出了有趣的问题

。他们的焦点,
作为重农主义者的焦点,

是, 事实上,在这些客观
的生产条件上。

例如,他们还研究
了阶级斗争。

他们对工资的理解

与客观有关,
如果你愿意的话,权力关系,

资本和劳动力的议价能力。

但又一次 , 工厂, 机器,
劳动分工,

农业用地
以及发生在上面的事情.

所以
当时发生的大革命——

顺便说一句, 这
在经济学课上并不经常讲授——

现行经济

制度 我们所拥有

的称为“新古典经济学”的经济学思想

是逻辑完全改变了。

它在两个方面发生了变化。

它从对客观条件的关注转变为
对主观条件的关注。

让我解释一下我的意思。

客观的,就像我刚才说的那样。

主观的,从某种意义上说,
所有的注意力都集中

在不同类型的个人如何
做出决定上。

好的,所以工人正在最大限度
地选择休闲与工作。

消费者正在最大化
他们所谓的效用,

这是幸福的代表,

而公司正在最大化他们的利润。

这背后的想法是,
然后我们可以把它加起来,

然后我们看到它变成了什么,

这些漂亮的、花哨
的供求曲线

产生了一个价格,

一个均衡价格。

这是一个均衡价格,
因为我们还添加

了许多牛顿物理方程

,其中重心
是组织原理的重要组成部分。

但这里的第二点
是均衡价格或价格

揭示了价值。

所以这里的革命是
从客观到主观的转变,

而且逻辑不再
是价值是什么,

它是如何被确定的,经济

的再生产
潜力是什么,

从而导致价格理论,

而是 反过来

:揭示价值的价格和交换理论

现在,这是一个巨大的变化。

这不仅仅是一项学术活动
,尽管这可能很吸引人。

它会影响我们衡量增长的方式。

它影响我们如何引导
经济生产更多的某些活动,

更少的其他活动,

以及我们如何为
某些活动提供比其他活动更多的报酬。

它也只是让你想,

你知道,
如果你不是一个价值创造者,你是否乐意起床,如果你不能确定

价格体系本身又如何

我提到它会
影响我们对输出的看法。

例如,如果我们只将

那些有价格的活动包括在 GDP 中,

就会发生各种非常奇怪的事情。

女权主义经济学家
和环境

经济学家实际上已经写
了很多关于这一点的文章。

让我给你一些例子。

如果你嫁给你的保姆,
GDP会下降,所以不要这样做。

不要试图这样做,好吗?

因为可能
在付费之前的活动仍在完成

但不再付费。

(笑声)

如果你污染,GDP就会上升。

仍然不要这样做,但如果你这样做,
你会帮助经济。

为什么? 因为我们实际上
必须花钱请人清理它。

现在,真正有趣的

金融部门的金融在 GDP 中发生了什么。

顺便说一句,这也是许多经济学家不知道的事情,
我总是感到惊讶

直到 1970 年,

大部分金融部门
甚至都没有计入 GDP。

这是一种间接的,
也许

是不知情的,在重农主义者的眼中仍然被

视为一种移动的东西,
实际上并没有产生任何新的东西。

因此,仅包括
那些有明确价格的活动。

例如,如果你去
获得抵押贷款,你会被收取费用。

这进入了国内生产总值以及
国民收入和产品核算。

但是,例如,
净利息支付没有,

银行给你贷款时所赚取的

利息与
他们为存款支付的利息之间的差异。

那不包括在内。

所以做会计的人
开始查看一些数据,

这些数据开始
显示金融规模

和这些净利息

支付实际上在大幅增长。

他们
称之为“银行问题”。

这些人
实际上是在联合国内部

的一个名为“
国民账户系统”(SNA) 的小组中工作的人。

他们称其为“银行问题”,

例如,“天哪,这件事
太大了,我们甚至不包括在内。”

因此,他们没有停止并实际
制作 Tableau Economique,

也没有提出一些

古典学派也在
询问实际发生的基本问题,即

经济中不同类型活动之间的分工,

他们只是给这些
净利息支付一个 名称。

所以商业银行,他们称之为
“金融中介”。

这进入了 NIPA 账户。

投资银行
被称为“冒险活动”

。如果我没有正确解释这一点,

那条红线显示了整个

金融中介与其他金融中介
相比增长速度有多快

。 经济
,蓝线,工业。

所以这非常不寻常,

因为实际发生的事情,
以及我们今天所知道的,

还有不同的人在
写这件事,

这里的数据
来自英格兰银行

,很多金融业从 1970 年代
开始实际上在做的事情

和 80

年代基本上是为自己融资:

融资融资融资。

我的意思是金融、
保险和房地产。

事实上,在英国,

大约
10% 到 20% 的金融

进入实体经济,进入工业,

例如能源部门
、制药

业、IT 部门,

但其中大部分又回到
了那个领域 首字母缩写词,FIRE:

金融、保险和房地产。

它非常方便地称为 FIRE。

现在,这很有趣,因为事实上,

这并不是说金融
的好坏,

而是说金融的好坏程度

,只需给它一个名字,

因为它实际上产生了收入

而不是 停下来问:
“它到底在做什么?” ——

这是一个错失的机会。

同样,在实体经济中,
在工业本身中,发生了什么?

这种对价格
和股价

的真正关注造成了再投资的巨大问题

同样,
重农学派和古典派都

对经济中产生的价值实际上被再投资的程度给予了真正的关注

所以我们今天拥有的是
一个超金融化的工业部门

,其中越来越多
的利润和净收入

实际上并没有
重新投入生产、

人力资本培训
、研发,

而只是被
抽走 回购自己的股票的条款,

这增加了股票期权
,事实上,这

是许多高管获得报酬的方式。

而且,你知道,一些
股票回购绝对没问题,

但这个
系统完全不合时宜。

我在这里向您

展示的这些数字表明,在过去 10 年中,
466 家 S 和 P 500 公司仅在回购股票上

就花费了超过 4 万亿美元

如果你
把它放在宏观经济层面上,你会看到什么,

所以如果我们看一下
商业投资总额,

它是 GDP 的百分比,

你也会看到
商业投资水平下降。

这是一个问题。

顺便说一句,这
对技能和创造就业机会来说是一个巨大的问题。

您可能听说
这些天来有很多关注

,“机器人会抢走我们的工作吗?”

嗯,机械化
实际上已经占据了几个世纪的工作岗位,

但只要将利润
再投资于生产,

那就没关系了:新的工作岗位出现了。

但事实上,缺乏再投资
是非常危险的。

同样,在制药行业,
例如,价格是如何设定的,

它如何不考虑
在经济中创造

价值的集体方式的这些客观条件,这是非常有趣
的。

所以在你有
很多不同参与者的领域——

当然是公共的、私人的,还有
第三部门的组织——

创造价值

,我们在这个领域实际衡量价值的方式

是通过价格体系本身。

价格揭示价值。

因此,最近,当

一种抗生素的价格在
一夜之间上涨了 400% 时

,CEO 被问到:
“你怎么能做到这一点?

人们实际上需要那种抗生素。

这是不公平的。”

他说,“嗯,我们有道德

义务让
价格随市场承受而变化”,

完全否定了这样一个事实
,例如,在美国,

美国国立卫生研究院
每年在医学研究上花费超过 300 亿美元


这实际上导致了这些药物。

因此,同样,缺乏
对这些客观条件的关注

,只是让价格体系
本身揭示价值。

现在,这不仅仅是
一个学术练习

,尽管它可能很有趣。

所有这一切
对我们如何衡量产出、

我们如何引导经济

、你是否
觉得自己有生产力

、我们最终
帮助、支持哪些部门

以及让人们
为成为其中的一员而感到自豪,都非常重要。

事实上,回到那句话

,布兰克费恩
会这么说并不奇怪。

他是对的。

在我们实际衡量经济中的
生产、生产力

和价值的方式中,

高盛的员工当然
是最有生产力的。

他们实际上是赚得最多的。

他们的劳动力价格
正在揭示他们的价值。

但这当然会变成同义反复。

因此,确实需要重新考虑。

我们需要重新思考
我们如何衡量产出

,事实上
世界各地都有一些惊人的实验。

例如,在新西兰,他们现在有了
一个国民幸福指数。

在不丹,他们也在
考虑幸福和幸福的指标。

但问题是我们不能
只是添加东西。

我们确实必须暂停

,我认为这应该
是暂停的时刻,

因为我们看到

自金融危机以来实际上没有什么变化,

以确保
我们也不会混淆

价值提取和价值创造,

所以看看包括的内容,
而不仅仅是增加更多,

以确保我们不会
混淆租金和利润。

古典音乐的租金
是关于不劳而获的收入。

今天,当在经济学中谈论租金时,租金

只是
对具有竞争力的价格的不完美,如果你消除一些不对称性

,它可能会被竞争消除

其次,我们当然可以将
活动引导到经典所说

的“生产边界”。

这不应该是我们对他们,

大的,坏的金融与
好的,其他部门。

我们可以改革金融。

危机过后,在某些方面确实失去了机会。

我们本
可以征收金融交易税,

这将奖励
长期主义而不是短期主义,

但我们没有决定在全球范围内这样做。

我们可以。 我们可以改变主意。

我们还可以设立
新型机构。

例如,世界各地有不同类型的
公共金融机构

实际上提供耐心、
长期、承诺的资金

,帮助小公司成长,帮助
基础设施和创新的发生。

但这不应该只是关于输出。

这不应该只是
关于产出率。

作为一个社会,我们也应该停下

来问:我们到底在创造什么价值?

最后,我只想以
本周我们正在

庆祝登月 50 周年这一事实结束。

这要求公共部门
、私营部门

以各种方式进行投资和创新

而不仅仅是在航空领域。

它包括对
营养和材料等领域的投资。

在此过程中发生了许多实际
错误。

事实上,政府所做的只是利用
其全部采购权力,

例如为
那些自下而上的解决方案提供动力

,其中一些解决方案失败了。

但失败是价值创造的一部分吗?

或者他们只是错误?

或者我们实际上如何
培养实验

、反复试验、错误和错误?

贝尔实验室,作为
AT和T的研发实验室,

其实来自一个
政府相当有魄力的时代。

它实际上要求AT和T
,为了保持其垄断地位,

它必须将其利润再投资
于实体经济、

创新和电信以外的创新。

那就是历史,
贝尔实验室的早期历史。

那么,我们如何才能围绕再投资获得这些新条件

共同投资

针对
我们这个时代一些最大挑战(

如气候变化)的新型价值呢?

这是一个关键问题。

但我们也应该问自己,

如果有过
净现值计算

或成本效益

分析,是否

在一代人的时间内尝试去月球再返回,

我们可能不会开始。

所以感谢上帝,

因为我是经济学家
,我可以告诉你,

价值不仅仅是价格。

谢谢你。

(掌声)