Why its so hard to make healthy decisions David Asch

It’s April of 2007,

and Jon Corzine,
the Governor of New Jersey,

is in this horrific car accident.

He’s in the right front
passenger seat of this SUV

when it crashes on
the Garden State Parkway.

He’s transported
to a New Jersey trauma center

with multiple broken bones
and multiple lacerations.

He needs immediate surgery,
seven units of blood,

a mechanical ventilator
to help him breathe

and several more operations along the way.

It’s amazing he survived.

But perhaps even more amazing,

he was not wearing a seat belt.

And, in fact, he never wore a seat belt,

and the New Jersey state troopers
who used to drive Governor Corzine around

used to beg him to wear a seat belt,

but he didn’t do it.

Now, before Corzine
was Governor of New Jersey,

he was the US Senator from New Jersey,

and before that, he was
the CEO of Goldman Sachs,

responsible for taking
Goldman Sachs public,

making hundreds of millions of dollars.

Now, no matter what you think
of Jon Corzine politically

or how he made his money,

nobody would say that he was stupid.

But there he was,

an unrestrained passenger
in a car accident,

at a time when every American knows
that seat belts save lives.

This single story reflects
a fundamental weakness

in our approach
to improving health behavior.

Nearly everything we tell doctors
and everything we tell patients

is based on the idea
that we behave rationally.

If you give me information, I will process
that information in my head,

and my behavior will change as a result.

Do you think Jon Corzine didn’t know
that seat belts save lives?

Do you think he, like,
just didn’t get the memo?

(Laughter)

Jon Corzine did not have
a knowledge deficit,

he had a behavior deficit.

It’s not that he didn’t know better.

He knew better.

It’s that he didn’t do better.

Instead, I think the mind
is a high-resistance pathway.

Changing someone’s mind
with information is hard enough.

Changing their behavior with information

is harder still.

The only way we’re going to make
substantial improvements

in health and health care

is to make substantial improvements
in the behavior of health and health care.

If you hit my patellar tendon
with a reflex hammer,

my leg is going to jerk forward,

and it’s going to jerk forward
a lot faster and a lot more predictably

than if I had to think about it myself.

It’s a reflex.

We need to look for the equivalent
behavioral reflexes

and hitch our health care wagon to those.

Turns out, though,

that most conventional approaches
to human motivation

are based on the idea of education.

We assume that if people
don’t behave as they should,

it’s because they didn’t know any better.

“If only people knew that smoking
was dangerous, they wouldn’t smoke.”

Or, we think about economics.

The assumption there is that
we’re all constantly calculating

the costs and benefits
of every one of our actions

and optimizing that to make
the perfectly right, rational decision.

If that were true, then all we need to do

is to find the perfect
payment system for doctors

or the perfect co-payments
and deductibles for patients,

and everything would work out.

A better approach lies
in behavioral economics.

Behavioral economists recognize
that we are irrational.

Our decisions are based on emotion,

or they’re sensitive to framing
or to social context.

We don’t always do what’s in our own
long-term best interests.

But the key contribution
to behavioral economics

is not in recognizing
that we are irrational;

it’s recognizing that we are irrational
in highly predictable ways.

In fact, it’s the predictability
of our psychological foibles

that allows us to design
strategies to overcome them.

Forewarned is forearmed.

In fact, behavioral economists often use

precisely the same behavioral
reflexes that get us into trouble

and turn them around to help us,

rather than to hurt us.

We see irrationality play out
in something called “present bias,”

where the outcomes in front of us
are much more motivating

than even more important outcomes
far in the future.

If I’m on a diet –
and I’m always on a diet –

(Laughter)

and someone offers me a luscious-looking
piece of chocolate cake,

I know I should not
eat that chocolate cake.

That chocolate cake will land
on that part of my body – permanently –

where that kind of food naturally settles.

But the chocolate cake
looks so good and delicious,

and it’s right in front of me,

and the diet can wait ‘til tomorrow.

I used to love the comedian Steven Wright.

He would have these Zen-like quips.

My favorite one was this:

“Hard work pays off in the future,

but laziness pays off right now.”

(Laughter)

And patients also have present bias.

If you have high blood pressure,

even if you would desperately
like to avoid a stroke,

and you know that taking
your antihypertensive medications

is one of the best ways
to reduce that risk,

the stroke you avoid is far in the future
and taking medications is right now.

Almost half of the patients who are
prescribed high blood pressure pills

stop taking them within a year.

Think of how many lives we could save

if we could solve just that one problem.

We also tend to overestimate
the value of small probabilities.

This actually explains
why state lotteries are so popular,

even though they return
pennies on the dollar.

Now, some of you
may buy lottery tickets –

it’s fun, there’s the chance
you might strike it rich …

But let’s face it:

this would be a horrible way
to invest your retirement savings.

I once saw a bumper sticker –
I am not making this up – that said,

“State lotteries are a special tax
on people who can’t do math.”

(Laughter)

It’s not that we can’t do the math,

it’s that we can’t feel the math.

And we also pay much too much
attention to regret.

We all hate the feeling of missing out.

So, actually, there was
this recent lottery,

a mega-jackpot lottery,

that had a huge payoff,
something like over a billion dollars.

And everyone in my office
is pooling money to buy lottery tickets,

and I’m not having any of this.

There I am, like, swaggering
around the office,

“Lotteries are a special tax
on people who can’t do math.”

(Laughter)

And then it hits me:

uh oh.

What if they win?

(Laughter)

I’m the only one who shows up
at work the next day.

(Laughter)

Now, it’s not that I didn’t want
my colleagues to win.

I just didn’t want them to win without me.

Now, it would have been easier
if I had just taken my 20-dollar bill

and put it into the office shredder,

and the results would have been the same.

Even though I knew
I shouldn’t participate,

I handed over my $20 bill,

and I never saw it again.

(Laughter)

We’ve done a bunch
of experiments with patients

in which we give them
these electronic pill bottles

so we can tell whether
they’re taking their medication or not.

And we reward them with a lottery.

They get prizes.

But they only get prizes

if they had taken
their medication the day before.

If not, they get a message
that says something like,

“You would have won a hundred dollars,

but you didn’t take your medicine
yesterday, so you don’t get it.”

Well, it turns out, patients hate that.

They hate the sense of missing out,

and because they can anticipate
that feeling of regret

and they’d like to avoid it,

they’re much more likely
to take their medications.

Harnessing that sense
of hating regret works.

And it leads to the more general point,

which is: once you recognize
how people are irrational,

you’re in a much better
position to help them.

Now, this kind of irrationality works out
even in men’s restrooms.

So, for those of you
who don’t frequent urinals,

let me break this down for you.

(Laughter)

There is pee all over the floor.

(Laughter)

And it turns out that you
can solve this problem

by etching the image of a fly
in the back of the urinal.

(Laughter) (Applause)

And it makes perfect sense.

(Laughter)

If I see a fly,

I’m gonna get that fly.

(Laughter)

That fly is going down.

(Laughter)

Now, this naturally begs the question
that if men can aim,

why were they peeing
on the floor in the first place?

In fact, if they were going
to pee on the floor,

why pee in front of the urinal?

You could pee anywhere.

(Laughter)

And the same thing works in health care.

We had a problem in our hospital

in which the physicians
were prescribing brand-name drugs

when a generic drug was available.

Each one of the lines on this graph
represents a different drug.

And they’re listed according to how often
they’re prescribed as generic medications.

Those are the top are prescribed
as generics 100 percent of the time.

Those down at the bottom
are prescribed as generics

less than 20 percent of the time.

And we’d have meetings with clinicians
and all sorts of education sessions,

and nothing worked –

all the lines are pretty much horizontal.

Until, someone installed
a little piece of software

in the electronic health record

that defaulted the prescriptions
to generic medications

instead of the brand-name drugs.

Now, it doesn’t take a statistician

to see that this problem
was solved overnight,

and it has stayed solved ever since.

In fact, in the two and a half years
since this program started,

our hospital has saved 32 million dollars.

Let me say that again: 32 million dollars.

And all we did was make it easier

for the doctors to do what they
fundamentally wanted to do all along.

It also works to play into
people’s notions of loss.

We did this with a contest
to help people walk more.

We wanted everyone to walk
at least 7,000 steps,

and we measured their step count

with the accelerometer
on their cell phone.

Group A, the control group,
just got told whether they had walked

7,000 steps or not.

Group B got a financial incentive.

We gave them $1.40 for every day
they walked 7,000 steps.

Group C got the same financial incentive,

but it was framed as a loss
rather than a gain:

$1.40 a day is 42 dollars a month,

so we gave these participants 42 dollars
at the beginning of each month

in a virtual account that they could see,

and we took away $1.40 for every day
they didn’t walk 7,000 steps.

Now, an economist would say
that those two financial incentives

are the same.

For every day you walk 7,000 steps,
you’re $1.40 richer.

But a behavioral economist
would say that they’re different,

because we’re much more motivated
to avoid a $1.40 loss

than we are motivated
to achieve a $1.40 gain.

And that’s exactly what happened.

Those in the group that received $1.40
for every day they walked 7,000 steps

were no more likely to meet their goal
than the control group.

The financial incentive didn’t work.

But those who had a loss-framed incentive

met their goal 50 percent
more of the time.

It doesn’t make economic sense,
but it makes psychological sense,

because losses loom larger than gains.

And now we’re using loss-framed incentives
to help patients walk more,

lose weight

and take their medications.

Money can be a motivator.

We all know that.

But it’s far more influential
when it’s paired with psychology.

And money, of course,
has its own disadvantages.

My favorite example of this
involves a daycare program.

The greatest sin you can commit in daycare
is picking up your kids late.

No one is happy.

Your kids are crying
because you don’t love them.

(Laughter)

The teachers are unhappy
because they leave work late.

And you feel terribly guilty.

This daycare program in Israel
decided they wanted to stop this problem,

and they did something that many
daycare programs in the US do,

which is they installed
a fine for late pickups.

And the fine they chose was 10 shekels,

which is about three bucks.

And guess what happened?

Late pickups increased.

And if you think about it,
it makes perfect sense.

What a deal!

For 10 shekels –

(Laughter)

you can keep my kids all night!

(Laughter)

They took a perfectly strong
intrinsic motivation not to be late,

and they cheapened it.

What’s worse, when they
realized their mistake

and they took away
the financial incentive,

the late pickups still stayed
at the high level.

They had already poisoned
the social contract.

Health care is full
of strong intrinsic motivations.

We have doctors and patients
who already want to do the right thing.

Financial incentives can help,

but we shouldn’t expect
money in health care

to do all of the heavy lifting.

Instead, perhaps the most powerful
influencers of health behavior

are our social interactions.

Social engagement works in health care,

and it works in two directions.

First, we fundamentally care
what others think of us.

And so one of the most powerful ways
to change our behavior

is to make our activities
witnessable to others.

We behave differently
when we’re being observed

than when we’re not.

I’ve been to some restaurants
that don’t have sinks in the bathrooms.

Instead, when you step out,
the sink is outside

in the main part of the restaurant,

where everyone can see
whether you wash your hands or not.

Now, I don’t know for sure,

but I am convinced
that handwashing is much greater

in those particular settings.

We are always on our best behavior
when we’re being observed.

In fact, there was this amazing study

that was done in an intensive care unit
in a Florida hospital.

The handwashing rates were very low,
which is dangerous, of course,

because it can spread infection.

And so some researchers pasted
a picture of someone’s eyes over the sink.

It wasn’t a real person,
it was just a photograph.

In fact, it wasn’t even their whole face,
it was just their eyes looking at you.

(Laughter)

Handwashing rates more than doubled.

It seems we care so much
what other people think of us

that our behavior improves

even if we merely imagine
that we’re being observed.

And not only do we care
what others think of us,

we fundamentally model our behaviors
on what we see other people do.

And it all comes back to seat belts.

When I was a kid, I used to love
the “Batman” TV series with Adam West.

Everything that Batman
and Robin did was so cool,

and, of course, the Batmobile
was the coolest thing of all.

Now, that show aired from 1966 to 1968,

and at that time, seat belts
were optional accessories in cars.

But the producers of that show
did something really important.

When Batman and Robin
got in the Batmobile,

the camera would focus on their laps,

and you would see Batman and Robin
put on their seat belts.

Now, if Batman and Robin
put on their seat belts,

you can bet that I was going to wear
my seat belt, too.

I bet that show saved thousands of lives.

And again, it works in health care, too.

Doctors use antibiotics more appropriately
when they see how other doctors use them.

So many activities in health care
are hidden, they’re unwitnessed,

but doctors are social animals,

and they perform better
when they see what other doctors do.

So social influence works in health care.

So does tying it to notions of regret
or to loss aversion.

We would never think of using these tools
if we thought that everyone was rational

all the time.

Now, just to be clear:
I am not condemning rationality.

I mean, that really would be irrational.

But we all know that it’s
the nonrational parts of our minds

where we get courage,
creativity, inspiration

and everything else that sparks passion.

And we know something else, too.

We know that we can be much more effective
at improving health behavior

if we work with the irrational
parts of our nature

instead of ignoring them
or fighting against them.

When it comes to health care,

understanding our irrationality
is just another tool in our toolbox.

And harnessing that irrationality –

that may be the most rational move of all.

Thank you.

(Applause)

现在是 2007 年 4 月

,新泽西州州长乔恩·科辛 (Jon Corzine) 身陷

这场可怕的车祸。

当这辆 SUV 在花园州立公园大道上坠毁时,他坐在右前排乘客座位上

因多处骨折
和多处撕裂伤被送往新泽西州的创伤中心。

他需要立即进行手术、
七个单位的血液、一台

帮助他呼吸的机械呼吸机,

以及在此过程中还要进行几次手术。

他能活下来真是太神奇了。

但也许更令人惊奇的是,

他没有系安全带。

而且,事实上,他从来没有系过安全带,

曾经开车送科辛州长四处

走动的新泽西州警察也曾央求他系上安全带,

但他没有这样做。

现在,科尔津
在担任新泽西州州长之前,

他是新泽西州的美国参议员,

在此之前,他
是高盛的首席执行官,

负责将
高盛上市,

赚了数亿美元。

现在,无论你如何
看待 Jon Corzine 在政治上

或他如何赚钱,

没有人会说他是愚蠢的。

但他在那里,

一个
在车祸中不受约束的乘客,

此时每个美国人都
知道安全带可以挽救生命。

这个单一的故事反映

我们改善健康行为的方法的一个根本弱点。

几乎我们告诉医生
的一切和我们告诉病人的一切

都是基于
我们行为理性的想法。

如果你给我信息,我会
在脑海中处理这些信息

,我的行为也会因此而改变。

你认为 Jon Corzine 不
知道安全带可以挽救生命吗?

你认为他
只是没有收到备忘录吗?

(笑声)

Jon Corzine
没有知识缺陷,

他有行为缺陷。

并不是他不知道更好。

他更清楚。

是他没有做得更好。

相反,我认为头脑
是一个高阻力的途径。 用信息

改变一个人的想法
已经够难的了。

用信息改变他们的行为

更加困难。

我们要

在健康和医疗保健

方面做出实质性改善
的唯一方法是对健康和医疗保健行为做出实质性改善。

如果你用反射锤击打我的髌腱

我的腿会向前猛拉,

而且它会
比我自己考虑它更快、更可预测地向前

猛拉。

这是一种反射。

我们需要寻找等效的
行为反应

,并将我们的医疗保健车与这些反应联系起来。

然而,事实证明,大多数

人类动机的传统方法

都是基于教育的理念。

我们假设如果人们
没有表现出应有的行为,

那是因为他们没有更好的了解。

“如果人们知道吸烟
是危险的,他们就不会吸烟了。”

或者,我们考虑经济学。

假设
我们都在不断地计算

我们每一项行动的成本和收益,

并对其进行优化以
做出完全正确、理性的决定。

如果这是真的,那么我们需要做的

就是为医生找到完美的
支付系统

或为患者找到完美的共付
额和免赔额

,一切都会好起来的。

更好的方法
在于行为经济学。

行为经济学家认识
到我们是非理性的。

我们的决定是基于情感,

或者它们对框架
或社会背景很敏感。

我们并不总是做符合我们自己
长期最佳利益的事情。


对行为经济学

的关键贡献不是
承认我们是非理性的;而是承认我们是非理性的。

它认识到我们
以高度可预测的方式是非理性的。

事实上,正是我们心理弱点的可预测性

使我们能够设计
策略来克服它们。

有备则无患。

事实上,行为经济学家经常使用

完全相同的行为
反射,这些行为反射让我们陷入困境

并扭转它们来帮助我们,

而不是伤害我们。

我们看到非理性
在所谓的“当前偏见”中发挥作用,在这种情况

下,我们面前的

结果比未来更重要的结果更有动力

如果我正在节食——
而且我一直在节食——

(笑声

)有人给我一块看起来很甜美
的巧克力蛋糕,

我知道我不应该
吃那个巧克力蛋糕。

那个巧克力蛋糕会
落在我身体的那个部位——永久地

——那种食物自然定居的地方。

但是巧克力蛋糕
看起来很好吃

,就在我面前

,减肥可以等到明天。

我曾经喜欢喜剧演员史蒂文·赖特。

他会有这些禅宗般的俏皮话。

我最喜欢的一句话是:

“努力工作在未来有回报,

但懒惰现在有回报。”

(笑声

) 患者也有现在的偏见。

如果您患有高血压,

即使您非常
想避免中风,

并且您知道服用
抗高血压药物


降低这种风险的最佳方法之一,

那么您避免中风是遥不可及的
,服用药物是 现在。

几乎一半
服用高血压药的患者

在一年内停止服用。

想想

如果我们能解决这个问题,我们可以挽救多少生命。

我们也倾向于高估
小概率的价值。

这实际上解释了
为什么州彩票如此受欢迎,

即使它们
以美元回报便士。

现在,你们中的一些人
可能会买彩票——

这很有趣,
你有可能发大财……

但让我们面对现实吧:

这将是一种可怕
的投资退休储蓄的方式。

我曾经看到一个保险杠贴纸——
我不是编造的——上面

写着:“州彩票是
对不会数学的人征收的一种特殊税。”

(笑声

) 不是我们不会做数学,

而是我们感觉不到数学。

而且我们也过分
关注后悔。

我们都讨厌错过的感觉。

所以,实际上,
最近有一种彩票,

一种超级头奖彩票,

它有巨大的回报,
大约超过 10 亿美元。

我办公室里的每个人都在
凑钱买彩票,

而我没有这些。

我在那里,就像,
在办公室里大摇大摆,

“彩票是
对不会数学的人征收的一种特殊税。”

(笑声

) 然后我

突然想到:哦哦。

如果他们赢了怎么办?

(笑声)

我是唯一一个
第二天上班的人。

(笑声)

现在,我并不是不想让
我的同事赢。

我只是不想让他们在没有我的情况下获胜。

现在,
如果我把我的 20 美元

钞票放入办公室碎纸机会更容易

,结果也会一样。

尽管我知道
我不应该参加,但

我还是交出了我的 20 美元钞票

,我再也没有看到它。

(笑声)

我们已经对患者进行了
一系列实验

,我们给他们
这些电子药瓶,

这样我们就可以判断
他们是否正在服药。

我们用彩票奖励他们。

他们得到奖品。

但他们只有在前
一天服药的情况下才能获得奖品。

如果没有,他们会收到一条消息
,上面写着

“你本可以赢一百美元,

但你昨天没有吃药
,所以你没有得到它。”

好吧,事实证明,患者讨厌这样。

他们讨厌错过的感觉

,因为他们可以预料
到这种遗憾的感觉

并且他们想避免这种感觉,

所以他们更有
可能服用药物。

利用
那种讨厌后悔的感觉是有效的。

它引出了更普遍的观点,

那就是:一旦你认识
到人们是多么不理性,

你就可以更好
地帮助他们。

现在,这种非理性
甚至在男厕所也能奏效。

因此,对于
那些不经常使用小便池的人,

让我为您分解一下。

(笑声

) 地上到处都是尿。

(笑声

) 事实证明,你
可以

通过在小便池后面蚀刻一只苍蝇的图像来解决这个问题

(笑声) (掌声)

这完全有道理。

(笑声)

如果我看到一只苍蝇,

我会抓到那只苍蝇。

(笑声)

那只苍蝇正在下降。

(笑声)

现在,这自然引出了一个问题
,如果男人可以瞄准,

为什么他们
首先会在地板上撒尿?

事实上,如果他们要
在地板上小便,

为什么要在小便池前小便呢?

你可以在任何地方撒尿。

(笑声

) 同样的事情也适用于医疗保健。

我们的医院有一个问题,当有仿制药可用

时,
医生开的是品牌药

该图上的每条线
代表一种不同的药物。

并且它们是根据
它们被规定为通用药物的频率列出的。

这些是顶级的
100% 的时间都被规定为仿制药。

那些位于底部
的药物被规定为仿制药的

比例不到 20%。

我们会与临床医生会面
和各种教育课程,但

没有任何效果——

所有的线几乎都是水平的。

直到,有人在电子健康记录中安装
了一个小软件

将处方默认
为仿制药

而不是品牌药。

现在,不需要统计学家

就可以看出这个问题
在一夜之间就解决了,

并且从那以后就一直解决了。

事实上,在这个项目开始的两年半里

我们医院已经节省了 3200 万美元。

让我再说一遍:3200 万美元。

我们所做的只是

让医生们更
容易做他们一直想做的事情。

它还可以发挥
人们的损失观念。

我们通过比赛
来帮助人们走得更多。

我们希望每个人
至少走 7,000 步

,我们用手机

上的加速度计测量
了他们的步数。

A组,对照组,
刚刚被告知他们是否走了

7000步。

B组获得了经济激励。

他们每天走 7,000 步,我们给了他们 1.40 美元

C 组获得了相同的经济激励,

但它被认为是损失
而不是收益:

每天 1.40 美元是每月 42 美元,

所以我们在每个月初给这些参与者 42

美元的虚拟账户,他们可以看到

,我们为
他们每天不走 7,000 步而带走了 1.40 美元。

现在,经济学家会
说这两种经济激励措施

是相同的。

你每天走 7,000 步,
你就多赚 1.40 美元。

但是行为经济学家
会说它们是不同的,

因为我们更有
动力避免 1.40 美元的损失,而

不是我们
获得 1.40 美元的收益。

这正是发生的事情。 每天步行 7,000 步

获得 1.40 美元的组中的

人实现目标的可能性并不
比对照组高。

经济激励没有奏效。

但那些有损失框架激励的人实现目标的几率要高出

50
%。

这在经济上没有意义,
但在心理上是有意义的,

因为损失比收益更大。

现在我们正在使用以损失为框架的激励措施
来帮助患者多走路、

减肥

和服药。

金钱可以成为一种动力。

我们都知道。

但当它
与心理学配对时,它的影响力要大得多。

当然,金钱
也有它自己的缺点。

我最喜欢的例子
涉及日托计划。

您在托儿所犯下的最大罪过
就是迟到接孩子。

没有人是快乐的。

你的孩子在哭,
因为你不爱他们。

(笑声

) 老师们很不高兴,
因为他们下班很晚。

你感到非常内疚。

以色列的这个日托计划
决定他们想要阻止这个问题

,他们做
了美国许多日托计划所做的事情,

即他们
对迟到的接送服务设置了罚款。

他们选择的罚款是10谢克尔,

大约是三块钱。

猜猜发生了什么?

后期提货增加。

如果你仔细想想,
这完全有道理。

多么划算!

10 谢克尔——

(笑声)

你可以让我的孩子整晚待着!

(笑声)

他们有一个非常强大的
内在动机不迟到

,他们贬低了它。

更糟糕的是,当他们
意识到自己的错误

并取消
了经济激励时

,后期皮卡仍然保持
在高水平。

他们已经毒化
了社会契约。

医疗保健充满
了强大的内在动力。

我们的医生和
患者已经想做正确的事。

经济激励措施可能会有所帮助,

但我们不应该指望
医疗保健方面的钱

能完成所有繁重的工作。

相反,也许
对健康行为最有影响力的因素

是我们的社交互动。

社会参与在医疗保健中

起作用,它在两个方向起作用。

首先,我们从根本上关心
别人对我们的看法。

因此,改变我们行为的最有效方法之一

就是让我们的
活动能够被他人看到。

当我们被

观察时,我们的行为与不被观察时不同。

我去过一些
浴室没有水槽的餐馆。

相反,当你走出去时
,水槽

在餐厅的主要部分外面

,每个人都可以看到
你是否洗手。

现在,我不确定,

但我相信

在这些特定环境中洗手要好得多。

当我们被观察时,我们总是表现得最好。

事实上,有一项惊人的研究

是在佛罗里达州医院的重症监护病房
进行的。

洗手率非常低,
这当然很危险,

因为它会传播感染。

所以一些研究人员
在水槽上贴了一张某人眼睛的照片。

那不是真人
,只是一张照片。

事实上,甚至不是他们的整张脸
,只是他们的眼睛在看着你。

(笑声)

洗手率增加了一倍多。

似乎我们非常
关心其他人对我们的看法,

以至于我们的行为得到了改善,

即使我们只是
想象我们正在被观察。

我们不仅关心
别人对我们的看法,

而且我们从根本
上根据我们看到的其他人的行为来塑造我们的行为。

这一切都回到了安全带。

当我还是个孩子的时候,我曾经很喜欢
亚当韦斯特的“蝙蝠侠”电视剧。

蝙蝠侠
和罗宾所做的一切都非常酷

,当然,蝙蝠车
是最酷的东西。

现在,该节目从 1966 年到 1968 年播出

,当时,安全带
是汽车的可选配件。

但是那个节目的制作人
做了一些非常重要的事情。

当蝙蝠侠和罗宾
坐上蝙蝠车时

,摄像机会聚焦在他们的腿上

,你会看到蝙蝠侠和
罗宾系上安全带。

现在,如果蝙蝠侠和
罗宾系上安全带,

你可以打赌
我也会系上安全带。

我敢打赌,该节目挽救了数千人的生命。

同样,它也适用于医疗保健。

当医生看到其他医生如何使用抗生素时,他们会更恰当地使用抗生素。

医疗保健
中的许多活动是隐藏的,没有目击者,

但医生是社会动物,

当他们看到其他医生的所作所为时,他们的表现会更好。

因此,社会影响在医疗保健中起作用。

将其与后悔或损失厌恶的概念联系起来也是如此

如果我们认为每个人一直都是理性的,我们就永远不会考虑使用这些工具

现在,要明确一点:
我不是在谴责理性。

我的意思是,这真的很不合理。

但我们都知道,
是我们头脑中的非理性部分

获得勇气、
创造力、灵感

和激发激情的其他一切。

我们也知道其他事情。

我们知道,

如果我们与我们天性中不合理的部分一起工作,

而不是忽视它们
或与它们作斗争,我们可以更有效地改善健康行为。

谈到医疗保健,

了解我们的非理性
只是我们工具箱中的另一个工具。

并利用这种非理性——

这可能是最理性的举措。

谢谢你。

(掌声)