Will automation take away all our jobs David Autor

Translator: Joseph Geni
Reviewer: Joanna Pietrulewicz

Here’s a startling fact:

in the 45 years since the introduction
of the automated teller machine,

those vending machines that dispense cash,

the number of human bank tellers
employed in the United States

has roughly doubled,

from about a quarter of a million
to a half a million.

A quarter of a million in 1970
to about a half a million today,

with 100,000 added since the year 2000.

These facts, revealed in a recent book

by Boston University
economist James Bessen,

raise an intriguing question:

what are all those tellers doing,

and why hasn’t automation
eliminated their employment by now?

If you think about it,

many of the great inventions
of the last 200 years

were designed to replace human labor.

Tractors were developed

to substitute mechanical power
for human physical toil.

Assembly lines were engineered

to replace inconsistent human handiwork

with machine perfection.

Computers were programmed to swap out

error-prone, inconsistent
human calculation

with digital perfection.

These inventions have worked.

We no longer dig ditches by hand,

pound tools out of wrought iron

or do bookkeeping using actual books.

And yet, the fraction of US adults
employed in the labor market

is higher now in 2016

than it was 125 years ago, in 1890,

and it’s risen in just about every decade

in the intervening 125 years.

This poses a paradox.

Our machines increasingly
do our work for us.

Why doesn’t this make our labor redundant
and our skills obsolete?

Why are there still so many jobs?

(Laughter)

I’m going to try to answer
that question tonight,

and along the way, I’m going to tell you
what this means for the future of work

and the challenges that automation
does and does not pose

for our society.

Why are there so many jobs?

There are actually two fundamental
economic principles at stake.

One has to do with human genius

and creativity.

The other has to do
with human insatiability,

or greed, if you like.

I’m going to call the first of these
the O-ring principle,

and it determines
the type of work that we do.

The second principle
is the never-get-enough principle,

and it determines how many jobs
there actually are.

Let’s start with the O-ring.

ATMs, automated teller machines,

had two countervailing effects
on bank teller employment.

As you would expect,
they replaced a lot of teller tasks.

The number of tellers per branch
fell by about a third.

But banks quickly discovered that it
also was cheaper to open new branches,

and the number of bank branches
increased by about 40 percent

in the same time period.

The net result was more branches
and more tellers.

But those tellers were doing
somewhat different work.

As their routine,
cash-handling tasks receded,

they became less like checkout clerks

and more like salespeople,

forging relationships with customers,

solving problems

and introducing them to new products
like credit cards, loans and investments:

more tellers doing
a more cognitively demanding job.

There’s a general principle here.

Most of the work that we do

requires a multiplicity of skills,

and brains and brawn,

technical expertise and intuitive mastery,

perspiration and inspiration
in the words of Thomas Edison.

In general, automating
some subset of those tasks

doesn’t make the other ones unnecessary.

In fact, it makes them more important.

It increases their economic value.

Let me give you a stark example.

In 1986, the space shuttle Challenger

exploded and crashed back down to Earth

less than two minutes after takeoff.

The cause of that crash, it turned out,

was an inexpensive rubber O-ring
in the booster rocket

that had frozen on the launchpad
the night before

and failed catastrophically
moments after takeoff.

In this multibillion dollar enterprise

that simple rubber O-ring

made the difference
between mission success

and the calamitous death
of seven astronauts.

An ingenious metaphor
for this tragic setting

is the O-ring production function,

named by Harvard economist Michael Kremer

after the Challenger disaster.

The O-ring production function
conceives of the work

as a series of interlocking steps,

links in a chain.

Every one of those links must hold
for the mission to succeed.

If any of them fails,

the mission, or the product
or the service,

comes crashing down.

This precarious situation
has a surprisingly positive implication,

which is that improvements

in the reliability
of any one link in the chain

increases the value
of improving any of the other links.

Concretely, if most of the links
are brittle and prone to breakage,

the fact that your link
is not that reliable

is not that important.

Probably something else will break anyway.

But as all the other links
become robust and reliable,

the importance of your link
becomes more essential.

In the limit, everything depends upon it.

The reason the O-ring was critical
to space shuttle Challenger

is because everything else
worked perfectly.

If the Challenger were
kind of the space era equivalent

of Microsoft Windows 2000 –

(Laughter)

the reliability of the O-ring
wouldn’t have mattered

because the machine would have crashed.

(Laughter)

Here’s the broader point.

In much of the work that we do,
we are the O-rings.

Yes, ATMs could do
certain cash-handling tasks

faster and better than tellers,

but that didn’t make tellers superfluous.

It increased the importance
of their problem-solving skills

and their relationships with customers.

The same principle applies
if we’re building a building,

if we’re diagnosing
and caring for a patient,

or if we are teaching a class

to a roomful of high schoolers.

As our tools improve,

technology magnifies our leverage

and increases the importance
of our expertise

and our judgment and our creativity.

And that brings me
to the second principle:

never get enough.

You may be thinking, OK, O-ring, got it,

that says the jobs that people do
will be important.

They can’t be done by machines,
but they still need to be done.

But that doesn’t tell me
how many jobs there will need to be.

If you think about it,
isn’t it kind of self-evident

that once we get sufficiently
productive at something,

we’ve basically
worked our way out of a job?

In 1900, 40 percent of all US employment

was on farms.

Today, it’s less than two percent.

Why are there so few farmers today?

It’s not because we’re eating less.

(Laughter)

A century of productivity
growth in farming

means that now,
a couple of million farmers

can feed a nation of 320 million.

That’s amazing progress,

but it also means there are
only so many O-ring jobs left in farming.

So clearly, technology can eliminate jobs.

Farming is only one example.

There are many others like it.

But what’s true about a single product
or service or industry

has never been true
about the economy as a whole.

Many of the industries
in which we now work –

health and medicine,

finance and insurance,

electronics and computing –

were tiny or barely existent
a century ago.

Many of the products
that we spend a lot of our money on –

air conditioners, sport utility vehicles,

computers and mobile devices –

were unattainably expensive,

or just hadn’t been invented
a century ago.

As automation frees our time,
increases the scope of what is possible,

we invent new products,
new ideas, new services

that command our attention,

occupy our time

and spur consumption.

You may think some
of these things are frivolous –

extreme yoga, adventure tourism,

Pokémon GO –

and I might agree with you.

But people desire these things,
and they’re willing to work hard for them.

The average worker in 2015

wanting to attain
the average living standard in 1915

could do so by working
just 17 weeks a year,

one third of the time.

But most people don’t choose to do that.

They are willing to work hard

to harvest the technological bounty
that is available to them.

Material abundance has never
eliminated perceived scarcity.

In the words of economist
Thorstein Veblen,

invention is the mother of necessity.

Now …

So if you accept these two principles,

the O-ring principle
and the never-get-enough principle,

then you agree with me.

There will be jobs.

Does that mean there’s
nothing to worry about?

Automation, employment, robots and jobs –

it’ll all take care of itself?

No.

That is not my argument.

Automation creates wealth

by allowing us to do
more work in less time.

There is no economic law

that says that we
will use that wealth well,

and that is worth worrying about.

Consider two countries,

Norway and Saudi Arabia.

Both oil-rich nations,

it’s like they have money
spurting out of a hole in the ground.

(Laughter)

But they haven’t used that wealth
equally well to foster human prosperity,

human prospering.

Norway is a thriving democracy.

By and large, its citizens
work and play well together.

It’s typically numbered
between first and fourth

in rankings of national happiness.

Saudi Arabia is an absolute monarchy

in which many citizens
lack a path for personal advancement.

It’s typically ranked 35th
among nations in happiness,

which is low for such a wealthy nation.

Just by way of comparison,

the US is typically ranked
around 12th or 13th.

The difference between these two countries

is not their wealth

and it’s not their technology.

It’s their institutions.

Norway has invested to build a society

with opportunity and economic mobility.

Saudi Arabia has raised living standards

while frustrating
many other human strivings.

Two countries, both wealthy,

not equally well off.

And this brings me
to the challenge that we face today,

the challenge that
automation poses for us.

The challenge is not
that we’re running out of work.

The US has added 14 million jobs

since the depths of the Great Recession.

The challenge is that many of those jobs

are not good jobs,

and many citizens
cannot qualify for the good jobs

that are being created.

Employment growth in the United States
and in much of the developed world

looks something like a barbell

with increasing poundage
on either end of the bar.

On the one hand,

you have high-education, high-wage jobs

like doctors and nurses,
programmers and engineers,

marketing and sales managers.

Employment is robust in these jobs,
employment growth.

Similarly, employment growth
is robust in many low-skill,

low-education jobs like food service,

cleaning, security,

home health aids.

Simultaneously, employment is shrinking

in many middle-education,
middle-wage, middle-class jobs,

like blue-collar production
and operative positions

and white-collar
clerical and sales positions.

The reasons behind this contracting middle

are not mysterious.

Many of those middle-skill jobs

use well-understood rules and procedures

that can increasingly
be codified in software

and executed by computers.

The challenge that
this phenomenon creates,

what economists call
employment polarization,

is that it knocks out rungs
in the economic ladder,

shrinks the size of the middle class

and threatens to make us
a more stratified society.

On the one hand, a set of highly paid,
highly educated professionals

doing interesting work,

on the other, a large number
of citizens in low-paid jobs

whose primary responsibility is to see
to the comfort and health of the affluent.

That is not my vision of progress,

and I doubt that it is yours.

But here is some encouraging news.

We have faced equally momentous
economic transformations in the past,

and we have come
through them successfully.

In the late 1800s and early 1900s,

when automation was eliminating
vast numbers of agricultural jobs –

remember that tractor? –

the farm states faced a threat
of mass unemployment,

a generation of youth
no longer needed on the farm

but not prepared for industry.

Rising to this challenge,

they took the radical step

of requiring that
their entire youth population

remain in school
and continue their education

to the ripe old age of 16.

This was called the high school movement,

and it was a radically
expensive thing to do.

Not only did they have
to invest in the schools,

but those kids couldn’t work
at their jobs.

It also turned out to be
one of the best investments

the US made in the 20th century.

It gave us the most skilled,
the most flexible

and the most productive
workforce in the world.

To see how well this worked,
imagine taking the labor force of 1899

and bringing them into the present.

Despite their strong backs
and good characters,

many of them would lack
the basic literacy and numeracy skills

to do all but the most mundane jobs.

Many of them would be unemployable.

What this example highlights
is the primacy of our institutions,

most especially our schools,

in allowing us to reap the harvest

of our technological prosperity.

It’s foolish to say
there’s nothing to worry about.

Clearly we can get this wrong.

If the US had not invested
in its schools and in its skills

a century ago with
the high school movement,

we would be a less prosperous,

a less mobile and probably
a lot less happy society.

But it’s equally foolish
to say that our fates are sealed.

That’s not decided by the machines.

It’s not even decided by the market.

It’s decided by us
and by our institutions.

Now, I started this talk with a paradox.

Our machines increasingly
do our work for us.

Why doesn’t that make
our labor superfluous,

our skills redundant?

Isn’t it obvious that the road
to our economic and social hell

is paved with our own great inventions?

History has repeatedly offered
an answer to that paradox.

The first part of the answer
is that technology magnifies our leverage,

increases the importance, the added value

of our expertise,
our judgment and our creativity.

That’s the O-ring.

The second part of the answer
is our endless inventiveness

and bottomless desires

means that we never get enough,
never get enough.

There’s always new work to do.

Adjusting to the rapid pace
of technological change

creates real challenges,

seen most clearly
in our polarized labor market

and the threat that it poses
to economic mobility.

Rising to this challenge is not automatic.

It’s not costless.

It’s not easy.

But it is feasible.

And here is some encouraging news.

Because of our amazing productivity,

we’re rich.

Of course we can afford
to invest in ourselves and in our children

as America did a hundred years ago
with the high school movement.

Arguably, we can’t afford not to.

Now, you may be thinking,

Professor Autor has told us
a heartwarming tale

about the distant past,

the recent past,

maybe the present,
but probably not the future.

Because everybody knows
that this time is different.

Right? Is this time different?

Of course this time is different.

Every time is different.

On numerous occasions
in the last 200 years,

scholars and activists
have raised the alarm

that we are running out of work
and making ourselves obsolete:

for example, the Luddites
in the early 1800s;

US Secretary of Labor James Davis

in the mid-1920s;

Nobel Prize-winning economist
Wassily Leontief in 1982;

and of course, many scholars,

pundits, technologists

and media figures today.

These predictions strike me as arrogant.

These self-proclaimed oracles
are in effect saying,

“If I can’t think of what people
will do for work in the future,

then you, me and our kids

aren’t going to think of it either.”

I don’t have the guts

to take that bet against human ingenuity.

Look, I can’t tell you
what people are going to do for work

a hundred years from now.

But the future doesn’t hinge
on my imagination.

If I were a farmer in Iowa
in the year 1900,

and an economist from the 21st century
teleported down to my field

and said, “Hey, guess what, farmer Autor,

in the next hundred years,

agricultural employment is going to fall
from 40 percent of all jobs

to two percent

purely due to rising productivity.

What do you think the other
38 percent of workers are going to do?”

I would not have said, “Oh, we got this.

We’ll do app development,
radiological medicine,

yoga instruction, Bitmoji.”

(Laughter)

I wouldn’t have had a clue.

But I hope I would have had
the wisdom to say,

“Wow, a 95 percent reduction
in farm employment

with no shortage of food.

That’s an amazing amount of progress.

I hope that humanity
finds something remarkable to do

with all of that prosperity.”

And by and large, I would say that it has.

Thank you very much.

(Applause)

译者:Joseph
Geni 审稿人:Joanna

Pietrulewicz 有一个令人吃惊的事实:

在自动柜员机问世以来的 45 年里

那些自动取款的自动售货机,

在美国雇佣的银行柜员

人数大约翻了一番,

从大约 一百万的四分之一到
一百万的半。

1970 年的 25 万
到今天的 50 万左右,

自 2000 年以来增加了 10 万。波士顿大学经济学家詹姆斯·贝森

在最近的一本书中揭示了这些事实,

提出了一个有趣的问题:

所有这些出纳员都在做什么,

为什么现在自动化还没有
消除他们的就业机会?

如果你想一想,

过去 200 年的许多伟大发明

都是为了取代人类劳动而设计的。

拖拉机的开发是

为了用机械
动力代替人类的体力劳动。

装配线的设计

目的是用机器完美代替不一致的人工手工

计算机经过编程,可以用数字完美替换

容易出错、不一致的
人工计算

这些发明奏效了。

我们不再用手挖沟,不再

用锻铁敲打工具,

也不再用真书记账。

然而,2016
年在劳动力市场上就业的美国成年人

比例现在

高于 125 年前的 1890 年,

并且

在其间的 125 年中几乎每十年都在上升。

这构成了一个悖论。

我们的机器越来越多地
为我们工作。

为什么这不会让我们的劳动力变得多余
,让我们的技能过时?

为什么还有这么多工作?

(笑声)

今晚我将尝试回答
这个问题

,在此过程中,我将告诉
你这对工作的未来意味着什么,

以及自动化

给我们的社会带来和不带来的挑战。

为什么会有这么多工作?

实际上有两个基本的
经济原则处于危险之中。

其中之一与人类的天才

和创造力有关。

另一个
与人类的贪得无厌

或贪婪有关,如果你愿意的话。

我将把其中的第
一个称为 O 形环原则

,它决定
了我们所做的工作类型。

第二个原则
是永不满足的原则

,它决定了
实际有多少工作。

让我们从 O 形圈开始。

ATM,自动柜员机,

对银行柜员的就业有两个抵消作用。

正如您所料,
他们取代了许多柜员任务。

每个分支机构的柜员人数
减少了约三分之一。

但银行很快发现
开设新分行的成本也更低

,同期银行分行的数量
增加了约 40

%。

最终结果是更多的分支机构
和更多的柜员。

但那些出纳员所做的
工作有些不同。

随着日常
现金处理任务的

减少,他们不再像收银员,

而更像销售人员,

与客户建立关系,

解决问题

并向他们介绍
信用卡、贷款和投资等新产品:

更多的出纳员
从事认知要求更高的工作 .

这里有一个普遍的原则。

我们所做的大部分工作都

需要多种技能

、头脑和体力、

技术专长和直觉掌握、

汗水和灵感
,用托马斯·爱迪生的话来说。

一般来说,自动化
这些任务的某些子集

并不会使其他任务变得不必要。

事实上,这让它们变得更加重要。

它增加了它们的经济价值。

让我给你一个鲜明的例子。

1986 年,挑战者号航天飞机

在起飞后不到两分钟就爆炸并坠毁在地球上。

事实证明,那次坠机的原因

是助推火箭中的一个便宜的橡胶 O 形环

在前一天晚上在发射台上结冰,

在起飞后不久就发生了灾难性的故障。

在这个价值数十亿美元的企业

中,简单的橡胶 O 形环

决定
了任务的成功


七名宇航员的不幸死亡。

这种悲剧背景的一个巧妙隐喻

是 O 型环生产函数,它

由哈佛经济学家迈克尔·克雷默 (Michael Kremer)

在挑战者号灾难后命名。

O 型圈生产功能
将工作设想

为一系列互锁步骤,

链中的链接。

这些链接中的每一个都必须保持,
才能使任务成功。

如果其中任何一个失败

,任务、产品
或服务

就会崩溃。

这种不稳定的情况
有一个令人惊讶的积极含义,

即提高

链条中任何一个环节的可靠性会

增加
改善任何其他环节的价值。

具体来说,如果大多数链接
都很脆弱并且容易损坏

,那么您的
链接不那么可靠这一

事实并不那么重要。

无论如何,可能还有其他东西会破裂。

但是随着所有其他链接
变得健壮和可靠,

您的链接的重要性
变得更加重要。

在极限中,一切都取决于它。

O 形环对挑战者号航天飞机至关重要的原因

是因为其他一切
都运行良好。

如果挑战者

是微软 Windows 2000 的太空时代——

(笑声)

O 形环的可靠性
就无关紧要了,

因为机器会崩溃。

(笑声)

这是更广泛的观点。

在我们所做的大部分工作中,
我们都是 O 形圈。

是的,自动柜员机可以

比柜员更快更好地完成某些现金处理任务,

但这并没有让柜员变得多余。

它提高
了他们解决问题的能力

以及与客户的关系的重要性。

如果我们正在建造建筑物,

如果我们正在诊断
和照顾病人,

或者如果我们正在

给一屋子的高中生上课,同样的原则也适用。

随着我们工具的改进,

技术放大了我们的影响力,

并增加
了我们的专业知识

、判断力和创造力的重要性。

这让我
想到了第二个原则:

永远不够。

你可能会想,好吧,O 型圈,明白了,

这说明人们所做的工作
很重要。

它们不能由机器完成,
但仍然需要完成。

但这并不能告诉我
需要多少工作。

如果你想一想

,一旦我们
在某件事上获得足够的生产力,

我们基本上就已经
摆脱了工作,这不是不言而喻的吗?

1900 年,美国 40% 的就业

人员在农场工作。

今天,它不到百分之二。

为什么今天的农民这么少?

这不是因为我们吃得少了。

(笑声)

一个世纪
的农业生产力增长

意味着现在,
几百万农民

可以养活一个拥有 3.2 亿人口的国家。

这是惊人的进步,

但这也意味着
农业领域只剩下这么多 O 型圈工作。

很明显,技术可以消除工作。

农业只是一个例子。

还有很多其他人喜欢它。

但是,关于单一产品
、服务或行业的

真实情况,
对整个经济来说从来都不是真实的。

我们现在工作的许多行业——

健康和医药、

金融和保险、

电子和计算机——

在一个世纪前还很小或几乎不存在

我们花了很多钱购买的许多产品——

空调、运动型多功能车、

电脑和移动设备——

都非常昂贵,

或者只是
一个世纪前还没有发明。

随着自动化解放了我们的时间,
扩大了可能的范围,

我们发明了新产品、
新想法、新服务

,这些都引起了我们的注意,

占用了我们的时间

并刺激了消费。

你可能会认为其中
一些事情是轻浮的——

极限瑜伽、冒险旅游、

Pokémon

GO——我可能会同意你的看法。

但是人们渴望这些东西
,他们愿意为之努力。

2015 年的普通工人

想要达到
1915 年的平均生活水平,

一年只需工作 17 周,

即三分之一的时间。

但大多数人不会选择这样做。

他们愿意努力工作

以收获
可供他们使用的技术奖励。

物质丰富从未
消除感知的稀缺性。

用经济学家
托尔斯坦·凡勃伦的话来说,

发明是必然之母。

现在……

所以如果你接受这两个原则

,O 型圈原则
和永不满足原则,

那么你同意我的观点。

会有工作。

这是否意味着没有
什么可担心的?

自动化、就业、机器人和工作——

一切都会自己解决?

不,

那不是我的论点。

自动化

通过让我们
在更短的时间内完成更多工作来创造财富。

没有经济规律

说我们
会好好利用这些财富

,这值得担心。

考虑两个国家,

挪威和沙特阿拉伯。

这两个石油资源丰富的国家,

就像他们有钱
从地下的洞里喷出来一样。

(笑声)

但他们并没有很好地利用这些财富
来促进人类繁荣,

人类繁荣。

挪威是一个繁荣的民主国家。

总的来说,它的公民
可以一起工作和玩耍。

它通常

在国民幸福指数中排名第一到第四。

沙特阿拉伯是一个君主专制国家

,许多公民
缺乏个人进步的道路。

它的
幸福度通常在国家中排名第 35 位,

对于这样一个富裕的国家来说,这是很低的。

相比之下

,美国通常排
在第 12 或第 13 位左右。

这两个国家之间的

区别不是他们的财富

,也不是他们的技术。

这是他们的机构。

挪威已投资建设一个

有机会和经济流动性的社会。

沙特阿拉伯提高了生活水平,

同时挫败了
许多其他人类的努力。

两个国家,都很富裕,但

并不同样富裕。

这让我
想到了我们今天面临的挑战,

自动化给我们带来的挑战。

挑战不
在于我们没有工作了。

自大萧条以来,美国增加了 1400 万个工作岗位

挑战在于,其中许多工作

都不是好工作

,许多
公民没有资格获得

正在创造的好工作。

美国
和大部分发达国家的就业增长

看起来就像一个杠铃


杠铃两端的磅数都在增加。

一方面,

你有高学历、高薪的工作,

比如医生和护士、
程序员和工程师、

营销和销售经理。

这些工作的就业强劲,
就业增长。

同样,

食品服务、

清洁、安全、

家庭健康辅助等许多低技能、低教育水平的工作中,就业增长强劲。

与此同时,

许多中等教育、
中等工资、中产阶级的就业岗位正在萎缩,

如蓝领生产
和操作岗位

以及白领
文员和销售岗位。

这种收缩中间的原因

并不神秘。

许多中等技能工作

使用易于理解的规则和程序

,这些规则和程序可以越来越多
地编入软件

并由计算机执行。

这种现象造成的挑战

,经济学家称之为
就业两极分化,

是它破坏
了经济阶梯,

缩小了中产阶级的规模,

并有可能使我们
成为一个更加分层的社会。

一方面,一群高薪、
受过高等教育的专业人士

从事着有趣的工作,

另一方面,大量
从事低薪工作的公民,

其主要职责是
照顾富人的舒适和健康。

那不是我对进步的看法

,我怀疑它是你的。

但这里有一些令人鼓舞的消息。 过去,

我们也面临同样重大的
经济转型,

而且
我们成功地度过了难关。

在 1800 年代末和 1900 年代初,

当自动化正在消除
大量农业工作时——

还记得那辆拖拉机吗?

——农业州面临
大规模失业的威胁

,一代年轻人
不再需要在农场工作,

但还没有为工业做好准备。

为了迎接这一挑战,

他们采取了激进的措施

,要求
他们的所有青年都

留在学校
并继续接受教育

,直到 16 岁。

这被称为高中运动

,这是一件极其
昂贵的事情。

他们不仅
要投资学校,

而且那些孩子也不能
从事他们的工作。

事实证明,这也是

美国在 20 世纪做出的最佳投资之一。

它为我们提供了世界上最熟练
、最灵活

和最有生产力的
劳动力。

要想看看这有多好,
想象一下把 1899 年的劳动力

带到现在。

尽管他们强壮的背部
和良好的性格,

但他们中的许多人
缺乏基本的识字和算术技能,

只能做最平凡的工作。

他们中的许多人将失业。

这个例子强调的
是我们的机构,

尤其是我们的学校,

在让

我们收获技术繁荣的收获方面的首要地位。


没有什么可担心的是愚蠢的。

很明显,我们可能会弄错。

如果美国没有

一个世纪前
的高中运动中投资于其学校和技能,

我们将是一个不那么繁荣

、不那么流动、
可能更不幸福的社会。

但是
说我们的命运是注定的同样愚蠢。

这不是由机器决定的。

它甚至不是由市场决定的。

这是
由我们和我们的机构决定的。

现在,我以一个悖论开始了这次谈话。

我们的机器越来越多地
为我们工作。

为什么这不会让
我们的劳动变得多余,

我们的技能不会多余?

通向我们经济和社会地狱

的道路是由我们自己的伟大发明铺就的,这不是很明显吗?

历史一再
为这个悖论提供答案。

答案的第一部分
是,技术放大了我们的影响力,

增加

了我们的专业知识
、判断力和创造力的重要性和附加值。

那是O型圈。

答案的第二部分
是我们无尽的创造力

和无底的欲望

意味着我们永远不会得到足够的,
永远不会得到足够的。

总是有新的工作要做。

适应快速
的技术变革

带来了真正的挑战,这

在我们两极分化的劳动力市场

及其对经济流动性构成的威胁中最为明显

迎接这一挑战并不是自动的。

这不是没有成本的。

这并不容易。

但这是可行的。

这里有一些令人鼓舞的消息。

由于我们惊人的生产力,

我们很富有。

当然,我们有能力
为自己和我们的孩子投资,

就像一百年前美国
在高中运动中所做的那样。

可以说,我们不能不这样做。

现在,你可能在想,

奥托教授给我们讲了
一个

关于遥远的过去

、最近的过去,

也许是现在,
但可能不是未来的感人故事。

因为大家都知道
,这次不一样。

对? 这次不一样了吗?

当然这次不一样。

每次都不一样。

在过去的 200 年中,

学者和活动家
多次发出警报

,我们正在失去工作
并让自己过时:

例如,
1800 年代初期的卢德派; 1920 年代中期的

美国劳工部长詹姆斯戴维斯

; 1982 年

诺贝尔奖获得者经济学家
瓦西里·列昂蒂夫;

当然,还有今天的许多学者、

专家、技术专家

和媒体人物。

这些预测让我觉得傲慢。

这些自称的神谕
实际上是在说:

“如果我想不出人们
将来会为工作做什么,

那么你、我和我们的孩子

也不会想到它。”

我没有勇气

对人类的聪明才智下注。

听着,我不能告诉你一百年后
人们会做什么工作

但未来并不
取决于我的想象力。

如果我是 1900 年爱荷华州的一个农民,

21 世纪的一位经济学家
传送到我的田地

并说:“嘿,你猜怎么着,农夫奥特,

在接下来的一百年里,

农业就业人数
将从 40 “纯粹由于生产力的提高,所有工作的

百分比下降到 2%

你认为其他
38% 的工人会做什么?”

我不会说,“哦,我们得到了这个。

我们会做应用程序开发、
放射医学、

瑜伽教学、Bitmoji。”

(笑声)

我不会有任何线索。

但我希望我
能有智慧说:

“哇,农业就业减少了 95%

而且不缺食物。

这是一个惊人的进步。

我希望人类能
找到

与所有这些繁荣有关的非凡事情。 "

总的来说,我会说它有。

非常感谢你。

(掌声)