What is the tragedy of the commons Nicholas Amendolare

Imagine as a thought experiment
that you live in a small village

and depend on
the local fish pond for food.

You share the pond
with three other villagers.

The pond starts off with a dozen fish,
and the fish reproduce.

For every two fish, there will be
one baby added each night.

So, in order to maximize
your supply of food,

how many fish should you catch each day?

Take a moment to think about it.

Assume baby fish grow
to full size immediately

and that the pond begins at full capacity,

and ignore factors
like the sex of the fish you catch.

The answer? One, and it’s not just you.

The best way to maximize
every villager’s food supply

is for each fisherman to take
just one fish each day.

Here’s how the math works.

If each villager takes one fish,
there will be eight fish left over night.

Each pair of fish produces one baby,

and the next day, the pond
will be fully restocked with twelve fish.

If anyone takes more than one,
the number of reproductive pairs drops,

and the population
won’t be able to bounce back.

Eventually, the fish in the lake
will be gone,

leaving all four villagers to starve.

This fish pond is just one example
of a classic problem

called the tragedy of the commons.

The phenomenon was first described
in a pamphlet

by economist
William Forster Lloyd in 1833

in a discussion of
the overgrazing of cattle

on village common areas.

More than 100 years later, ecologist
Garrett Hardin revived the concept

to describe what happens
when many individuals

all share a limited resource,

like grazing land,

fishing areas,

living space,

even clean air.

Hardin argued that these situations
pit short-term self-interest

against the common good,

and they end badly for everyone,

resulting in overgrazing,

overfishing,

overpopulation,

pollution,

and other social
and environmental problems.

The key feature of
a tragedy of the commons

is that it provides an opportunity for
an individual to benefit him or herself

while spreading out any negative effects
across the larger population.

To see what that means,
let’s revisit our fish pond.

Each individual fisherman is motivated

to take as many fish
as he can for himself.

Meanwhile, any decline
in fish reproduction

is shared by the entire village.

Anxious to avoid
losing out to his neighbors,

a fisherman will conclude that it’s in his
best interest to take an extra fish,

or two,

or three.

Unfortunately, this is the same conclusion
reached by the other fisherman,

and that’s the tragedy.

Optimizing for the self in the short term
isn’t optimal for anyone in the long term.

That’s a simplified example,
but the tragedy of the commons

plays out in the more complex systems
of real life, too.

The overuse of antibiotics has led to
short-term gains in livestock production

and in treating common illnesses,

but it’s also resulted in the evolution
of antibiotic-resistant bacteria,

which threaten the entire population.

A coal-fired power plant produces
cheap electricity for its customers

and profits for its owners.

These local benefits are helpful
in the short term,

but pollution from mining and burning coal
is spread across the entire atmosphere

and sticks around for thousands of years.

There are other examples, too.

Littering,

water shortages,

deforestation,

traffic jams,

even the purchase of bottled water.

But human civilization has proven it’s
capable of doing something remarkable.

We form social contracts,

we make communal agreements,

we elect governments,

and we pass laws.

All this to save our collective selves
from our own individual impulses.

It isn’t easy, and we certainly
don’t get it right nearly all of the time.

But humans at our best have shown
that we can solve these problems

and we can continue to do so
if we remember Hardin’s lesson.

When the tragedy of the commons applies,

what’s good for all of us
is good for each of us.

想象一下
,你住在一个小村庄里


靠当地的鱼塘觅食。


与其他三个村民共用池塘。

池塘一开始有十几条鱼,
然后鱼繁殖。

每两条鱼,
每晚将增加一个婴儿。

那么,为了最大化
你的食物供应,

你每天应该钓多少条鱼?

花点时间考虑一下。

假设幼鱼
立即长到全尺寸

,并且池塘开始满负荷运行,

并忽略
您捕获的鱼的性别等因素。

答案? 一,不只是你。

最大化
每个村民的食物供应的最好方法

是每个渔民
每天只捕一条鱼。

这是数学的工作原理。

如果每个村民拿一条鱼,
一夜之间就会剩下八条鱼。

每对鱼生一个婴儿

,第二天,池塘里
将满载十二条鱼。

如果有人服用多于一只,
繁殖对的数量就会下降

,人口
将无法反弹。

最终,湖里的鱼
会消失,

剩下的四个村民都饿死了。

这个鱼塘只是

被称为公地悲剧的经典问题的一个例子。

1833 年经济学家威廉·福斯特·劳埃德 (William Forster Lloyd)

在一本小册子中首次描述了这种现象,当时该小册子讨论了

村庄公共区域过度放牧的情况。

100 多年后,生态学家
加勒特·哈丁(Garrett Hardin)重新提出了这一概念,

以描述
当许多

人共享有限资源时会发生什么,

比如牧场、

渔区、

生活空间,

甚至是清洁的空气。

哈丁认为,这些情况
使短期的自身利益

与公共利益相冲突

,结果对每个人都不利,

导致过度放牧、

过度捕捞、

人口过剩、

污染

以及其他社会
和环境问题。 公地悲剧

的关键特征

是,它为个人提供了使自己受益的机会,

同时将任何负面影响
分散到更大的人群中。

要了解这意味着什么,
让我们重温一下我们的鱼塘。

每个渔民都有动力

为自己捕获尽可能多的鱼

同时,
鱼类繁殖的任何下降

都会由整个村庄共同承担。 渔民

急于避免
输给他的邻居,他

会得出结论,
多捞一条、两条或三条鱼对他最有利

不幸的是,这
与其他渔民得出的结论相同

,这就是悲剧。

短期内
为自己优化对任何人来说都不是长期的最佳选择。

这是一个简化的例子,
但公地悲剧也会

在更复杂
的现实生活系统中上演。

抗生素的过度使用
导致畜牧生产

和治疗常见疾病的短期收益,

但也导致
了抗生素耐药细菌的进化

,威胁到整个人口。

燃煤电厂
为客户生产廉价电力,

为业主生产利润。

这些当地利益
在短期内是有帮助的,

但采矿和燃烧煤炭造成的污染
会扩散到整个大气中,

并且会持续数千年。

还有其他例子。

乱扔垃圾、

缺水、

砍伐森林、

交通拥堵,

甚至购买瓶装水。

但是人类文明已经证明它
有能力做一些了不起的事情。

我们制定社会契约

,制定公共协议

,选举政府,

并通过法律。

所有这一切都是为了将我们的集体自我
从我们自己的个人冲动中拯救出来。

这并不容易,而且我们当然
不会几乎所有时间都做对。

但人类已经
证明我们可以解决这些问题

,如果我们记住哈丁的教训,我们就可以继续这样做

当公地悲剧发生时,

对我们所有人有益的事情
对我们每个人都有好处。