Why is it so hard to escape poverty AnnHeln Bay

Imagine that you’ve been unemployed
and seeking work for months.

Government benefit programs have helped
you cover rent, utilities, and food,

but you’re barely getting by.

Finally, you hear back
about a job application.

You receive your first paycheck in months,
and things seem to be turning around.

But there’s a catch.

Your new job pays just enough to
disqualify you from the benefit programs,

and not enough
to cover the same costs.

To make things worse, you have
to pay for transportation to work,

and childcare while you’re at the office.

Somehow, you have less money now
than when you were unemployed.

Economists call this demoralizing
situation the welfare trap—

one of the many different poverty traps
affecting millions of people

around the world.

Poverty traps are economic
and environmental circumstances

that reinforce themselves,
perpetuating poverty for generations.

Some poverty traps are tied
to an individual’s circumstances,

like a lack of access to healthy food
or education.

Others can affect entire nations,

such as cycles of corrupt government
or climate change.

But the cruel irony of welfare traps
in particular

is that they stem from the very policies
designed to battle poverty.

Most societies throughout history employed
some strategies

to help people in poverty
meet basic needs.

Before the 20th century,
religious groups and private charities

often led such initiatives.

Today, these are called welfare programs,

and they usually take the form
of government-provided subsidies

for housing, food, energy, and healthcare.

Typically, these programs
are means-tested,

meaning that only people who fall
below a certain income level

are eligible for benefits.

This policy is designed to ensure aid
goes to those who need it most.

But it also means people lose access
as soon as they earn more

than the qualification threshold,

regardless of whether or not they’re
financially stable enough to stay there.

This vicious cycle is harmful to both
those in poverty and those outside of it.

Mainstream economic models assume people
are rational actors

who weigh the cost and benefits
of their options

and choose the most advantageous
path forward.

If those in poverty know they’ll gain
no net benefit from working,

they’re incentivized to remain
in government assistance.

Of course, people work for many reasons,

including societal norms
and personal values.

But income is a major incentive
to pursuing employment.

And when less people take on new jobs,
the economy slows down,

keeping people in poverty

and potentially pushing people
on the cusp of poverty over the edge.

Some have suggested this feedback loop
could be removed

by eliminating government assistance
programs altogether.

But most agree the solution
is neither realistic nor humane.

So how can we redesign benefits in a way
that doesn’t penalize people for working?

Many countries have tried different
ways to circumvent this problem.

Some allow people to continue receiving
benefits for a given period

after finding a job,

while others phase out benefits
gradually as income increases.

These policies still remove some
financial incentive to work,

but the risk of a welfare trap is lower.

Other governments provide benefits like
education, childcare, or medical care

equally across all their citizens.

One proposed solution takes this idea
of universal benefits even further.

A universal basic income would provide
a fixed benefit to all members of society,

regardless of wealth or employment status.

This is the only known policy that could
entirely remove welfare traps,

since any earned wages would supplement
the benefit rather than replace it.

In fact, by creating a stable income floor
below which no one can fall,

basic income might prevent people from
falling into poverty in the first place.

Numerous economists and thinkers

have championed this idea
since the 18th century.

But for now, universal basic income
remains largely hypothetical.

Although it’s been tried in some
places on a limited scale,

these local experiments don’t tell us
much about how the policy

would play out across an entire nation—
or a planet.

Whatever strategy governments pursue,

solving the welfare trap requires
respecting people’s agency and autonomy.

Only by empowering individuals
to create long-term change

in their lives and communities

can we begin to break the cycle
of poverty.

想象一下,您已经失业
并找工作几个月了。

政府福利计划帮助
您支付房租、水电费和食品费用,

但您勉强过活。

最后,您会
收到一份工作申请的回复。

你在几个月内收到了第一笔薪水
,事情似乎正在好转。

但有一个问题。

您的新工作所支付的薪水刚好足以让
您丧失福利计划的资格

,但
不足以支付相同的费用。

更糟糕的是,你
必须支付上班的交通费

和在办公室时的托儿费用。

不知何故,你现在的钱
比你失业时少。

经济学家将这种令人沮丧的
情况称为福利

陷阱——影响全世界数百万人的众多不同贫困陷阱

之一。

贫困陷阱是自我强化的经济
和环境环境


使贫困代代相传。

一些贫困陷阱
与个人的情况有关,

例如无法获得健康食品
或教育。

其他可能会影响整个国家,

例如腐败政府
或气候变化的周期。

但福利陷阱尤其具有讽刺意味的

是,它们源于
旨在与贫困作斗争的政策。

历史上的大多数社会都采用了
一些策略

来帮助贫困人口
满足基本需求。

在 20 世纪之前,
宗教团体和私人慈善机构

经常领导此类倡议。

今天,这些被称为福利计划

,它们通常
采取政府

为住房、食品、能源和医疗保健提供补贴的形式。

通常,这些计划
都经过经济状况调查,

这意味着只有
低于特定收入水平的人才

有资格获得福利。

该政策旨在确保将援助
送到最需要的人手中。

但这也意味着人们
一旦收入

超过资格门槛,就会失去访问权,

无论他们的
财务状况是否足够稳定,可以留在那里。

这种恶性循环对
贫困人口和贫困人口之外的人都是有害的。

主流经济模型假设人们
是理性的行为

者,他们权衡其选择的成本和
收益,

并选择最有利的
前进道路。

如果贫困者知道他们不会
从工作中获得净收益,

他们就会被激励继续接受
政府援助。

当然,人们工作的原因有很多,

包括社会规范
和个人价值观。

但收入是
追求就业的主要动力。

当更少的人从事新工作时
,经济就会放缓,

使人们陷入贫困,

并可能将
处于贫困边缘的人们推向边缘。

一些人建议
可以

通过完全取消政府援助计划来消除这种反馈循环

但大多数人都同意这个解决
方案既不现实也不人道。

那么,我们如何才能以一种不惩罚人们工作的方式重新设计福利
呢?

许多国家已经尝试了不同的
方法来规避这个问题。

有些允许人们

在找到工作后在特定时期内继续领取福利,

而另一些则
随着收入的增加逐渐取消福利。

这些政策仍然消除了一些
工作的经济激励,

但福利陷阱的风险较低。

其他政府为所有公民平等地提供
教育、儿童保育或医疗保健

等福利。

一个提议的解决方案将这种
普遍利益的想法更进一步。

普遍的基本收入将为
社会所有成员提供固定的福利,

无论其财富或就业状况如何。

这是唯一可以
完全消除福利陷阱的已知政策,

因为任何赚取的工资都会
补充而不是取代福利。

事实上,通过建立一个
任何人都不能低于的稳定收入底线,

基本收入可能会从一开始就防止人们
陷入贫困。 自 18 世纪以来,

许多经济学家和思想家

都支持这一观点

但就目前而言,普遍基本收入
在很大程度上仍是假设性的。

尽管已经在某些
地方进行了有限规模的尝试,但

这些本地实验并没有告诉我们
太多关于该政策将如何在

整个国家
或一个星球上发挥作用的信息。

无论政府采取何种战略,

解决福利陷阱都需要
尊重人民的能动性和自主权。

只有赋予个人权力

,使其能够在他们的生活和社区中创造长期的变化,

我们才能开始打破
贫困的循环。