The security mirage Bruce Schneier

so security is two different things

right it’s a feeling and it’s a reality

and they’re different or you could feel

secure even if you’re not and you can be

secure even if you don’t feel it I mean

really we have two separate concepts

mapped onto the same word and what I

want to do in this talk is to split them

apart figuring out when they diverge and

how they converge and language is

actually a problem here there aren’t a

lot of good words for the concepts we’re

going to talk about so if you look at

security from economic terms it’s a

trade off every time you get some

security you’re always trading off

something and whether this is a personal

decision whether you gonna install a

burglar alarm in your home or a national

decision where you can invade some

foreign country you’re gonna trade off

something either money or time

convenience capabilities may be

fundamental liberties and the question I

asked when you look at it a security

anything is not whether this makes us

safer

but whether it’s worth the trade-off

you’ve heard in the past several years

the world is safer because Saddam

Hussein is not in power that might be

true but it’s not terribly relevant the

question is was it worth it and you know

you can make your own decision and then

you’ll decide whether the invasion was

worth it that’s how you think about

security in terms of the trade-off now

there’s often no right or wrong here

some of us have a burglar arm system at

home and some of us don’t handle to

depend on where we live whether we live

alone or have a family you know how much

cool stuff we have how much we’re

willing to accept the risk of theft

right in in politics also there are

different opinions a lot of times these

trade-offs are about more than just

security and I think that’s really

important now people have a natural

intuition about these trade-offs we make

them every day but last night in my

hotel room and I started double lock the

door or you and your car when you draw

here you know when we go eat lunch and

decide the foods not poison and we’ll

eat it and we make these trade-offs

again and again multiple times a day you

often don’t even notice them they’re

just part of being alive we all do it

every species does it right imagine a

rabbit in a field eating grass and the

rabbits gonna see a fox that rabbit will

make a security trade-off should I stay

or should I flee and if you think about

it the rabbits that are good at making

that trade-off will tend to live and

reproduce and the rabbits that are bad

at it will get eaten or starve so you’d

think that us as a successful species on

the planet right you me everybody would

be really good at making these

trade-offs yet it seems again and again

that we’re hopelessly bad at it right

and I think that’s a fundamentally

interesting question I’ll give you the

short answer the answer is we respond to

the feeling of security and not the

reality now most of the time that works

right most of the time feeling and

reality are the same certainly that’s

true for most of human prehistory right

we’ve developed this ability because it

makes evolutionary sense I mean one way

to think of it is that we’re highly

optimized for risk decisions that are

endemic to living in small family groups

in the East African Highlands 100,000 BC

2010 New York you know not so much now

there are several biases and risk

perception a lot of good experiments in

this and you can see certain biases that

come up again and again I’ll give you

four we tend to exaggerate spectacular

and rare risks and downplay common risks

so flying versus driving the unknown is

Recife riskier than a familiar one

example would be people fear kidnapping

by strangers when the data supports

kidnapping by relatives is much more

common this is for children

third personified risks are perceived to

be greater than anonymous risks so bin

Laden is scarier because he has a name

and the fourth is people underestimate

secure risks in situations they do

control and overestimate them in

situations they don’t control so once

you take up skydiving or smoking you

downplay the risks if a risk is thrust

upon you terrorism is a good example

you’ll overplay it because you don’t

feel like it’s in your control there are

a bunch of other of these biases these

cognitive biases that affect our risk

decisions

there’s the availability heuristic which

basically means we estimate the

probability of something by how easy it

is to bring instances of it to mind so

you guys imagine how that works if you

hear a lot about Tiger attacks let’s be

a lot of tigers around you don’t hear

about lion attacks aren’t a lot of lions

around this works until you invent

newspapers because what newspapers do is

they repeat again and again rare risks

and I tell people if it’s in the news

don’t worry about it because by

definition news is something that almost

never happens right when something is so

common it’s no longer news if a car

crashes domestic violence those are the

risks you worry about we’re also a

species of storytellers we respond to

stories more than data and there’s some

basic and numeracy going on I mean the

joke one two three many is kind of right

we’re really good at small numbers one

mango two mangoes three mangoes 10,000

mangoes 1000 mangoes it stole more

mangoes you can eat before they rot so

1/2 1/4 1/5 we’re good at that one in a

million one in a billion they’re both

almost never so we have trouble with the

risks that aren’t very common and what

these cognitive biases do is they act as

filters between us and reality right and

the result is that feeling and reality

get out of whack they get different now

you either have you know feeling you

feel more secure than you are there’s a

false sense of security or the other

away and there’s often a full sense of

insecurity I write a lot about security

theater which are products that make

people feel secure but don’t actually do

anything there’s no real word for stuff

that makes us secure but doesn’t make us

feel secure maybe it’s what the CIA

supposed to do for us so back to

economics if economics if the market

drives security and if people make

trade-offs based on the feeling of

security then the smart thing for

companies to do for the economic

incentives are to make people feel

secure right and there are two ways to

do this one you can make people actually

secure and hope they notice or two you

can make people just feel secure and

hope they don’t notice right so what

makes people notice but a couple of

things understanding right of the

security of the risks the threats the

countermeasures how they work but if you

know stuff you’re more likely to have

your feelings match reality enough real

world examples helps now we all know the

crime rate in our neighborhood because

we live there and we get a feeling about

it that basically matches reality right

security theaters exposed when it’s

obvious that it’s not working properly

okay so what makes people not notice

well a poor understanding right if you

don’t understand the risks you don’t

ascend the costs you’re likely to get

the trade-off wrong and your feeling

doesn’t match reality but not enough

examples there’s an inherent problem

with low probability events if for

example terrorism almost never happens

it’s really hard to judge the efficacy

of counter-terrorist measures

night I mean this is why you you know

you keep sacrificing virgins and while

your unicorn defenses are working just

great

there’s aren’t enough examples of

failures also feelings that are clouding

the issues right the cognitive biases

are talking about earlier fears folk

beliefs right basically an inadequate

model of reality so let me complicate

things right I have feeling and reality

I want to add a third element I want to

add model a feeling and model in our

ahead

reality is the outside world it doesn’t

change it’s real my it’s a feeling is

based on our intuition model is based on

reason that’s basically the difference

uh in a primitive and simple world

there’s really no reason for a model

maybe because this feeling is close to

reality you don’t need a model but in a

modern and complex world you need models

to understand a lot of the risks we face

you know there’s no feeling about germs

you need a model to understand them so

this model is an intelligent reputation

of reality it’s of course limited by

science by technology right we couldn’t

have a germ theory of disease before we

invented the microscope to see them it’s

limited by our cognitive biases but it

has the ability to override our feelings

where do we get these models we get them

from others we get them from religion

from culture teachers elders couple

years ago I was in South Africa on

safari the tracker I was with grew up in

Kruger National Park he had some very

complex models on how to survive and it

depends if you attacked by a lion or a

leopard or a rhino and or elephant and

one you had to run away and when you

couldn’t run away and when you had a

climate tree when you could never climb

a tree I would have you know died and in

a day all right but he was born there

and he understood how to survive right I

was born in New York City I could take

it him to New York and he would have

died in a day

right because we had different models

based on our different experiences

models can come from the media from our

elected officials right think of models

of terrorism a child kidnapping airline

safety car safety models who come from

industry and a - I’m following are our

surveillance cameras ID cards a quite a

lot of our computer security models come

from there a lot of models come from

science and health models are a great

example think of cancer of bird flu

swine flu SARS I mean all of our

feelings of security about those

diseases come from models given to us

really by science filter through the

media right so models can change right

models are not static as we become more

comfortable in our environments our

model can move closer to our feelings so

an example might be if you go back a

hundred years ago when electricity was

first becoming common there were a lot

of fears about it I mean there are

people who were afraid to push doorbells

because electricity in there and that

was dangerous right for us

we’re very faasil around electricity

which changed light bulbs without even

thinking about it

right our model of security around

electricity it’s something we were we

were born into you know it hasn’t

changed as we were growing up and and

we’re good at it right or think of the

risks I’m on the internet across

generations how your parents approach

the Internet security versus how you do

versus how are our kids will you know

models eventually fade into the

background

you know intuitive just another word for

familiar right so as your model is close

to reality and converges with feelings

you often don’t even know it’s there

so a nice example of this came from last

year and swine swine flu when swine flu

first appeared the initial news caused a

lot of overreaction

now it was it had a name which made it

scarier than the regular flu even though

is more deadly and people thought

doctors should be able to deal with it

so was there was that feeling of lack of

control and those two things made the

risk more than it was as as the novelty

wore off the months went by there was

some amount of Tolerance people got used

to it right there was no new data but

there was less fear by autumn people

thought the doctor should have solved

this already and there’s kind of a

bifurcation people had to choose between

sort of fear and and an acceptance

actually fear an indifference that kind

of choose suspicion and when the vaccine

appeared last winter there are a lot of

people a surprising number who refused

to get it it’s a nice example of how

people’s feelings of security change how

their model changes sort of wildly with

no new information with no new input

this kind of thing happens a lot but

give it one more complication and we

have feeling model reality I have a very

relativistic view of security I think it

depends on the observer and most

security decisions have a variety of

people involved and stakeholders with

specific trade-offs will try to

influence the decision and I call that

their agenda and you see agenda this is

marketing this is politics trying to

convince you to have one model versus

another trying to convince you to ignore

a model and you trust your feelings

marginalizing people with models you

don’t like maybe this is not uncommon

now example a great example is the risk

of smoking in the history the past 50

years the smoking risk shows how a model

changes it also shows how an industry

fights against the model it doesn’t like

I compare that to the second hand smoke

debate no probably about 20 years behind

think about seatbelts when I was a kid

no one wore a seat belt

nowadays no kid will let you drive if

you’re not wearing a seat belt I compare

that to the airbag debate probably about

thirty years behind all examples of

models changing what we learn is that

changing models is hard right models are

hard to dislodge if they equal your

feelings you don’t even know you have a

model and there’s another cognitive bias

I’ll call confirmation bias where we

tend to accept data that confirms our

beliefs and reject data that contradicts

our beliefs so evidence against our

model we’re likely to ignore even if

it’s compelling has to get very

compelling before I’ll pay attention new

models that extend long periods of time

are hard global warming is a great

example we’re terrible at models that

span 80 years now we can do to the next

harvest we can often do till our kids

grow up but 80 years we’re just not good

at so it’s a very hard model to accept

you know we can have both models in our

head simultaneously or that kind of you

know that kind of problem where we have

is holding both beliefs together are the

cognitive dissidence eventually the new

model replaced the old model strong

feelings can create a model by September

11th created a social security model and

a lot of people’s heads also personal

experiences with crime can do it

personal health scare health scare in

the news you’ll see is called flash mob

events by spy psychiatrists

right they can create a model

instantaneously because they’re very

emotive so in the technological world we

don’t have experience to judge models

and and we rely on others we rely on

proxies I mean this works as long as

it’s the correct others right we rely on

government Asians to tell us what

pharmaceuticals are safe I flew here

yesterday I didn’t check the air of

airplane you know I relied on some other

group to determine whether my plane was

safe to fly we’re here none of us feared

the roof is gonna collapse on us not

because we checked but because we’re

pretty sure the building codes here are

good I mean we we it’s a model we just

accept pretty much by faith and that’s

okay now what we want is people to get

familiar enough with better models right

have it reflected in their feelings to

allow them to make security trade-offs

now when use these go out of whack you

sort of have you have two options one

you can fix people’s feelings right

directly appeal to feelings it’s

manipulation but it can work the second

more honest way is to actually fix the

model right change happens slowly the

smoking debate took 40 years and that

was an easy one but some of this stuff

is hard I mean really though information

seems like our best hope and and I lied

member I said feeling or feeling model

realities in reality doesn’t change it

actually does we live in a technological

world reality changes all the time so we

might have for the first time in our

species feeling chases model model

chases reality reality is moving they

might never catch up right we don’t know

right but in the long term both feeling

and reality are important and I want to

close with two quick stories to

illustrate this 1982 I know people

remember this there was a

epidemic of tylenol poisonings the

United States it’s a horrific story

someone took a bottle Tylenol put poison

in it

close it up put it back on the shelf

someone else bought it and died this

terrified people there are a couple of

copycat attacks there wasn’t any real

risk but people were scared and this is

how the tamper-proof drug industry was

invented those chamber of caps that came

from this it’s complete security theater

you know as a homework assignment think

of ten ways to get around it give you

one a syringe right but it made people

feel better it made their feeling of

security more match to the reality

last story a few years ago a friend of

mine gave birth visited her in the

hospital turns out when a baby’s born

now they put an RFID brace on the baby

put a corresponding one on the mother

said anyone other than the mother takes

the baby out of the maternity ward alarm

goes off I said well that’s kind of neat

I wonder how rampant baby snatching is

that hospitals I go home I look it up it

basically never happens but if you think

about it if you are a hospital and you

need to take a baby away from its mother

on other room to run some tests you

better have some good security theater

or she’s gonna rip your arm off so it’s

important for us those of us who design

security will look at the security

policy or even look at public policy in

a ways that effects security right it’s

not just a reality it’s feeling in

reality what’s important is that they be

about the same it’s important that if

our feelings match reality we make

better security trade-offs thank you

所以安全是两件不同的事情,

对,它是一种感觉,它是一种现实

,它们是不同的,或者

即使你没有,你也会感到

安全,即使你没有感觉到,你也可以感到安全我的意思

是我们真的有两个独立的

映射到同一个词上的概念,我

想在本次演讲中将它们

分开,弄清楚它们何时分歧以及

它们如何收敛,语言

实际上是一个问题

,对于我们的概念没有很多好词

重新讨论,所以如果你

从经济角度来看安全性,

每次你获得一些

安全性时,你总是在权衡

一些东西,这是否是个人

决定

,你是在家中安装防盗警报器还是在家里安装防盗警报器

您可以入侵某个

外国的国家决定

您将在金钱或时间上进行交易

便利能力可能是

基本自由,

当您将其视为安全时,我问的问题

不是这是否可以 让我们

更安全,

但是否值得

你在过去几年听到

的权衡,世界更安全,因为萨达姆

侯赛因没有掌权,这可能是

真的,但它并不是非常相关,

问题是它是否值得,你知道

您可以做出自己的决定,然后

您将决定入侵是否

值得,这就是您

在权衡取舍方面考虑安全性的方式现在

这里通常没有对错我们中的

一些人家里有防盗系统

我们中的一些人不

依赖于我们住在哪里无论我们是

独自生活还是有家庭你知道

我们有多少很酷的东西我们

愿意接受

政治上的盗窃风险也有

不同的意见 很多时候,这些

权衡不仅仅是关于

安全性,我认为这真的很

重要,现在人们对

我们每天都在做的这些权衡有一种自然的直觉,

但昨晚在我的

酒店房间里,我开始双

锁门 或者您 还有你的车,当你

在这里画画时,你知道我们什么时候去吃午饭,

决定食物无毒,我们会

吃掉它,我们

一天又一次地做出这些权衡,你

通常甚至没有注意到它们

这只是活着的一部分 我们都这样做

每个物种都做对了 想象一只

兔子在田野里吃草

兔子会看到一只狐狸 兔子会

在我留下

还是逃跑时做出安全权衡 如果你认为 关于

它,

擅长权衡取舍的兔子往往会生存和

繁殖,而不

擅长它的兔子会被吃掉或饿死,所以你会

认为我们是地球上一个成功的物种,

你我每个人

将非常擅长进行这些

权衡,但似乎我们一次又一次

地在这方面做得不好

,我认为这是一个从根本上

有趣的问题我会给你一个

简短的答案答案是我们回应

的感觉 安全,而不是

现在大多数的现实

大多数时候感觉和

现实都是一样的,这

对于大多数人类史前史来说当然是正确的,

我们已经开发了这种能力,因为它具有

进化意义我的意思是

一种思考方式是我们高度

优化

生活在

东非高地小家庭群体中的风险决策 公元前 100,000 年

2010 年纽约 你知道的不多 现在

有几个偏见和风险

感知 在这方面有很多很好的实验

,你可以看到

出现了某些偏见 我会一次又一次地给你

四个,我们倾向于夸大壮观

和罕见的风险并淡化常见风险,

所以飞行与驾驶未知的

累西腓比一个熟悉的例子风险更大

,当数据支持被亲戚绑架时,人们害怕被陌生人

绑架是 更

常见的是对于儿童来说,

第三人格化的风险被认为

比匿名风险更大,因此本

拉登更可怕,因为他有一个名字

和 第四,人们

在他们可以控制的情况下低估安全风险,

而在

他们无法控制的情况下高估安全风险,所以一旦

你开始跳伞或吸烟,你就会

淡化风险,如果风险

强加给你恐怖主义是一个很好的例子,

你会夸大 因为你不

觉得它在你的控制之中

还有很多其他的偏见 这些

认知偏见会影响我们的风险

决策 可用性启发式这

基本上意味着我们

通过带来实例的难易程度来估计某事的概率

记住这一点,所以

你们想象一下,如果你

听到很多关于老虎袭击的

事情,让我们周围有很多老虎,没有听说

过狮子袭击,

在你发明报纸之前,周围没有很多狮子,

因为什么 报纸所做的是

他们一次又一次地重复罕见的风险

,我告诉人们如果它出现在新闻中

,不要担心,因为根据

定义,新闻是几乎

永远不会发生的事情 t 当某件事如此

普遍时,如果车祸不再是

新闻 一二三多是对的

我们非常擅长小数量 一

芒果 二芒果 三芒果 10,000

芒果 1000 芒果 它偷走了更多的

芒果 你可以在它们腐烂之前吃掉 所以

1/2 1/4 1/5 我们很好

在百万分之一的情况下,他们

几乎从来没有,所以我们对

不太常见的风险有麻烦,而

这些认知偏见的作用是它们充当

我们和现实之间的过滤器

,结果是 感觉和

现实不合时宜 他们变得不同

现在你要么知道

感觉自己比现在更安全 有一种

虚假的安全感 要么另一种

远离而且经常有一种完全的

不安全感 我写了很多关于安全

剧院的文章 是 p 让

人们感到安全但实际上并没有做

任何事情的产品 没有真正的词来形容

那些让我们安全但不会让我们

感到安全的东西 也许这就是中央情报局

应该为我们做的事情 所以回到

经济学 如果经济学 如果市场

驱动安全性,如果人们

根据安全感进行权衡,

那么

公司为经济

激励做的明智之举就是让人们感到

安全,有两种方法可以

做到这一点,你可以让人们真正

安全并且 希望他们注意到一两个 你

可以让人们感到安全并

希望他们没有注意到正确 所以是什么

让人们注意到但有几

件事 了解

风险的安全性 威胁

对策 它们如何工作,但如果

你知道的话 你更有可能让

你的感受与

现实相符 ly 匹配现实 正确的

安全剧院

当它明显

无法正常工作时暴露出来

  • 错了,你的感觉

与现实不符,但没有足够的

例子

低概率事件存在固有问题,

例如恐怖主义几乎从未发生过

很难判断夜间

反恐措施的有效性

我的意思是这就是为什么你 知道

你一直在牺牲处女,虽然

你的独角兽防御工作

很好,

但没有足够多的失败例子,

也没有让问题蒙上阴影的感觉,

认知偏见

正在谈论早期的恐惧,民间

信仰基本上是一个不充分

的现实模型,所以让我 把事情复杂化

我有感觉和现实

我想添加第三个元素 我想

在我们的 ahe 中添加一个感觉和模型

ad

现实是外面的世界 它不会

改变 它是真实的 我这是一种感觉 是

基于我们的直觉 模型是基于

理性 这基本上是不同的

呃在一个原始而简单的世界

中 真的没有模型的理由

也许是因为这种感觉是 接近

现实,您不需要模型,但在

现代和复杂的世界中,您需要模型

来了解我们面临的许多风险

您知道对细菌没有感觉

您需要一个模型来理解它们,所以

这个模型是一个明智的声誉

现实当然受到

科学技术的限制,

在我们发明显微镜之前,我们不可能有疾病的细菌理论

来观察它们,它

受到我们的认知偏见的限制,但它

有能力超越我们的感受

,我们从哪里得到这些模型

我们从其他人那里得到它们 我们

从文化

老师长辈那里得到它们

关于如何生存的非常复杂的模型,这

取决于你是否被狮子、

豹子、犀牛和/或大象攻击

,你必须逃跑,什么时候你

不能逃跑,什么时候你有

气候树,什么时候可以 永远不要

爬树 我希望你知道

有一天他会死,但他出生在那里

,他知道如何生存,我

出生在纽约市,我可以

带他去纽约,他会

死在 天是

对的,因为我们根据不同的经验有不同的模型

模型可以来自媒体来自我们的

民选官员正确想想

恐怖主义模型一个儿童绑架航空公司

安全车安全模型来自

工业和 - 我正在关注的是我们的

监视 相机 ID 卡

我们的很多计算机安全模型都

来自那里 很多模型来自

科学和健康模型就是一个很好的

例子 想想禽流感

猪流感 SARS 我的意思是我们所有

的安全感

疾病来自科学给我们的模型,

通过

媒体过滤,模型可以改变正确的

模型不是静态的,因为我们

在我们的环境中变得更加舒适,我们的

模型可以更接近我们的感受,所以

一个例子可能是如果你回去

一百年前,当电

刚开始普及时

,人们对它有很多恐惧,我的意思是有些

人害怕按门铃,

因为那里有电,这

对我们来说很危险

灯泡甚至没有

考虑

它对我们围绕电力的安全模型

这是

我们出生的东西你知道它

在我们成长的过程中没有改变而且

我们很擅长正确或想想

我所面临的风险 在互联网上跨

代你的父母如何

处理互联网安全与你如何做

与我们的孩子如何你会知道

模型最终淡入

你知道的背景 itive 只是

熟悉权利的另一个词,因为您的模型

接近现实,并且与

您通常甚至不知道它的存在的感觉融合在一起,

所以一个很好的例子来自

去年和猪流感首次出现时的猪流感

最初的新闻 现在引起了

很多过度反应

,它的名字

使它比普通流感

更可怕,尽管它更致命,人们认为

医生应该能够处理它,

所以有一种缺乏

控制的感觉和这两件事

随着新奇事物的消失,风险比原来更大

人们不得不

在恐惧和

接受之间

做出选择

很多

拒绝接受的人数令人惊讶 这是一个很好的例子,说明

人们的安全感如何改变

他们的模型如何在

没有新信息没有新输入

的情况下疯狂地改变这种事情经常发生,但

给它一个更复杂的情况

我们感觉模型现实 我对安全有一个非常

相对论的观点 我认为这

取决于观察者,大多数

安全决策都涉及到各种各样的

人,利益相关者会在

特定的权衡下试图

影响决策,我称之为

他们的议程 你看议程这是

营销这是政治试图

说服你拥有一个模型而不是

另一个试图说服你忽略

一个模型并且你相信你的感觉

用你不喜欢的模型边缘化人们

也许这现在并不少见

示例a 一个很好的例子是

过去 50 年历史上的

吸烟风险 吸烟风险显示了模型如何

变化 它也显示了一个行业如何

反击 t 不喜欢的模型

我将其与二手烟辩论进行比较

没有可能落后大约 20 年

想想我小时候的安全带

现在没有人系安全带 没有孩子会让你开车 如果

你不系 一条安全带 我将

其与安全气囊辩论进行比较 可能

比所有改变模型的例子落后大约三十年

我们了解到的是,

改变模型很难正确的模型

如果它们等于你的

感觉,就很难被淘汰你甚至不知道你有一个

模型 还有另一种认知偏差,

我称之为确认偏差,我们

倾向于接受证实我们

信念的数据并拒绝与

我们的信念相矛盾的数据,因此

我们可能会忽略不利于我们模型的证据,即使

它很有

说服力,必须在我之前变得非常有说服力 会

注意 延长长时间的新模型

很难 全球变暖是一个很好的

例子 我们对

跨越 80 年的模型很糟糕 现在我们可以做到下一次

收获 我们经常可以做到直到我们的孩子 s

长大了,但 80 年我们只是不

擅长,所以这是一个很难接受的模型

你知道我们可以同时在我们的脑海中同时拥有这两个模型,

或者你

知道我们遇到的那种问题

是将两种信念结合在一起 是

认知上的异议最终新

模式取代了旧模式强烈的

感情可以在9月

11日之前创建一个模型创建了一个社会保障

模型很多人的头脑也有个人

犯罪经历可以做到

个人健康

恐慌新闻中的健康恐慌你' 会看到

被间谍精神病学家称为快闪事件,

他们可以立即创建一个模型,

因为它们非常

情绪化,所以在技术世界中,我们

没有判断模型的经验

,我们依赖其他人,我们依赖

代理我的意思是 只要

它是正确的 其他人就可以工作 我们依靠

政府的亚洲人来告诉我们哪些

药物是安全的 我昨天飞到这里

我没有检查飞机的空气

你知道我依靠 o 在其他一些

小组中确定我的飞机是否可以

安全飞行 我们在这里 我们没有人

担心屋顶会倒塌不是

因为我们检查了而是因为我们

很确定这里的建筑规范是

好的 我的意思是我们我们它是 一个我们

几乎凭信心接受的模型,

现在没关系,我们想要的是人们对

更好的模型足够熟悉,正确

地反映在他们的感受中,

让他们

现在可以在使用这些模型时做出安全权衡

有点你有两个选择一个

你可以正确地修复人们的感受

直接诉诸感受它的

操纵但它可以工作第二个

更诚实的方法是实际修复

模型正确的变化发生缓慢

吸烟辩论花了 40 年,这

很容易 一个但其中一些东西

很难我的意思是虽然信息

似乎是我们最好的希望而且我撒谎了

成员我说感觉或感觉

现实中的模型现实并没有改变它

实际上我们生活在技术中吗 逻辑

世界现实一直在变化,所以我们

可能第一次在我们的

物种中拥有感觉追逐模型模型

追逐现实现实在移动他们

可能永远赶不上我们不知道

正确但从长远来看感觉

和现实都很重要 我

想用两个简短的故事来结束

这件事 1982 我知道人们

记得美国发生了

一场泰诺中毒的流行

这是一个可怕的故事

有人拿了一瓶泰诺在里面放了毒药

合上 把它放回架子上

其他人买了它然后死了这个

吓坏了的人有几次

模仿攻击没有任何真正的

风险但人们很害怕这

就是发明防篡改药物行业的方式

那些来自这个的盖子的房间

它是完全安全的 戏剧,

你知道作为家庭作业

想十种方法来绕过它 给你

一个注射器 对,但它让人们

感觉更好 它让他们的

安全感更m 符合现实

最后一个故事 几年前我的一个

朋友生孩子 到医院探望她

原来是婴儿出生

现在他们给婴儿戴上 RFID 支架 给妈妈

戴上对应的

说除了妈妈以外的任何人都带

产科病房里的婴儿警报响起

我说那很好

我不知道医院抢婴儿有多猖獗

我回家我查了一下

基本上从来没有发生过 但是如果你考虑

一下 如果你是医院并且你

需要将婴儿从

另一个房间的母亲那里带走进行一些测试 你

最好有一些好的安全剧院

否则她会扯掉你的手臂 所以

对我们这些设计安全的人来说很重要

会查看安全

策略甚至查看 在公共政策中

以影响安全权利的方式这

不仅仅是现实它是现实中的感觉

重要的是它们

大致相同重要的是如果

我们的感觉与现实相符,我们会做出

更好的安全交易 fs 谢谢